INDEBTED THROUGH AND BY NEO-IMPERIALISM

1% own 43% of global wealth, while billions have no wealth at all.

Adopted from Paulo Nakatani and Rémy Herrera, The South Has Already Repaid its External Debt to the North: But the North Denies its Debt to the South, Monthly Review, June 2007, with updated adaptations on selective case countries, basing on (UNCTAD 2020, Developing country external debt: From growing sustainability concerns to potential crisis in the time of COVID-19); Eric Toussaint and Milan Rivié, Evolution of the external debt of developing countries between 2000 and 2019, Part 1,(2020); Threats over the external debt of Developing Countries Part 2 (November 2020); Developing countries in the stranglehold of debt Part 3 (April 2021); Eric Toussaint and Milan Rivié, An unsustainable burden of debt afflicts the peoples of Sub-Saharan Africa, Part 5 (May 2020); World Bank, International Debt Statistics 2021; Bank Negara Malaysia 2019, Profile of Malaysia’s External Debt – Bank Negara Malaysia; International Monetary Fund, The Debt Pandemic 2021; UNICEF, Families on the Edge, May 2021; UNFPA 2020.

1] INTRODUCTION

Since the onset of the global debt crisis in 1979 the transition and developing Global South economies had paid cumulative US$7.673 trillion in external debt service, see Paulo Nakatani and Rémy Herrera.

At the outbreak of the COVID-19 pandemic, external debt stocks of developing countries and economies in transition reached US$9.9 trillion, their highest level on record, more than twice their value of US$4.4 trillion registered in 2009, and more than four-fold their level of US$2.2 trillion in 2000, (UNCTAD 2020).

The external debts of developing and transition countries reached 29% of their GDP in 2019. The short-term debts rose to more than one-quarter of the total external debts.

Debt service on long-term external public debt (PPG) in developing and transition economies is debt sustainability (SDG) 17.4.1 where it measures “debt service as a proportion of exports of goods and services”. This indicator reflects a government’s ability to meet external creditor claims on the public sector through export revenues.

[Explanation under #13 Debt Servicing ¿].

This is of concern since low-income developing countries still rely predominantly on public financing to mobilise resources for structural transformation, yet also struggle the most with limited fiscal space given their shallow domestic financial and banking systems and limited options to refinance maturing debt obligations in the international financial markets.

The COVID-19 has translated into an ecological-epidemiological-economic shock that has put light to an epidemiological phenomenon to spotlight on the rapidly deteriorating debt sustainability in many developing countries. It threatens to turn what was already a dire situation prior to the pandemic into a series of sovereign defaults, (Rob Wallace, Alex Liebman, Luis Fernando Chaves and Rodrick Wallace, Covid19 and Circuits of Capital, Monthly Review, May 2020; John Bellamy Foster and Intan Suwandi, COVID-19 and Catastrophe Capitalism, Monthly Review, June 2020; Eric Toussaint and  Milan Rivié).

2] GLOBAL SOUTH DEBT

During the same period their debt has increased from US$618 billion in 1980 to US$3.150 trillion in 2006, according to figures published by the International Monetary Fund (IMF). The external debt of this group of countries, comprising 145 member states, will continue to grow throughout 2007, according to the IMF, to more than US$3.350 trillion. The debt of the Asian developing countries alone could rise to US$955 billion, even though they have already repaid, in interest and capital, far more than the original amount due in 1980!

Malaysia 2019 external debt was RM$231225.9 million, (Asia Development Bank, External Debt Outstanding in Asia and the Pacific, Asian Development Outlook, April 2020).

3] STIMULUS PACKAGES

Total external debt service of the Global South countries grew from 2.8 percent of GDP in 1980 to 4.0 percent in 1989 and 6.9 percent in 1999, before decreasing slowly to 5.2 percent in 2006, just above the 5.1 percent average for the period.

Finance Minister Tengku Datuk Seri Zafrul Abdul Aziz said Malaysia’s statutory debt is expected to hit 58.5% of gross domestic product (GDP) in 2021 due to the implementation of an additional RM20 billion PEMERKASA stimulus package on 18th. March 2021 to safeguard the nation’s economic growth from the impact of the Covid-19 pandemic.

Whereas the previous Perlindungan Ekonomi & Rakyat Malaysia PERMAI Assistance Package introduced on 18th January 2021 – the fifth economic stimulus package to date worth RM15 billion spread over 22 initiatives aimed at combating the Covid-19 outbreak – was deemed to be inadequate.

The Finance Minister indicated that the government will exhaust and maximise the use of the RM65 billion ceiling for the Covid-19 fund approved by the Parliament under the Temporary Measures for Government Financing (Coronavirus Disease 2019 [Covid-19]) Act.

According to a report to the Asian Development Bank, in September 2020, by Donghyun Park, Arief Ramayandi, Shu Tian stating inter alia that borrowing heavily for fiscal stimulus packages to support growth and provide relief for vulnerable groups whilst at the same time, private companies and households may be forced to borrow more to survive the economic impact of COVID-19…..In addition, the economic downturn challenges their capacity to service their existing debts. Therefore, despite widespread concerns about the current escalation of public debt and its sustainability, we should not lose sight of the potential risk from possible surges of private debt…..

However, the national household debt-to-Gross Domestic Product (GDP) ratio had already surged to a new peak of 93.3% as at December 2020 from its previous record high of 87.5% in June 2020, according to Bank Negara Malaysia (BNM).

4] GLOBAL SOUTH WEALTH DISPARITY

that an increase in inequality is likely to mean more people in poverty, because at the bottom end of the income scale there will be more people further away from the average.

To the ever increasing concentration of wealth, at the national level in favour of the dominant classes of the countries of the Global South, and at an international level in favour of the countries of the Global North. It explains in large part, over the last few years, the dramatic increase in intra– and international inequalities, as well as the increase in relative and absolute poverty. 

Income inequality has increased in most developed countries and in some middle-income countries, including China and India, since 1990, (United Nations, World Social Report 2020 – Inequality in a Rapid Changing World).

Countries where inequality has grown
are home to more than two thirds (71 per cent) of the world population. Yet growing
inequality is not a universal trend. The Gini coefficient of income inequality has declined
in most countries of Latin America and the Caribbean and in several African and Asian
countries over the last two decades.
Despite progress in some countries, income and wealth are increasingly concentrated
at the top.
The share of income going to the richest 1 per cent of the global population
increased in 46 out of 57 countries
and areas with data from 1990 to 2015.

Malaysia case scenario by UNICEF 2020 showed that low income female-headed households are exceptionally vulnerable, with higher rates of unemployment at 32% compared to the total heads of households. Female headed households also registered lower rates of access to social protection, with 57% having no access compared to 52% of total heads of households.


Meanwhile, the bottom 40 per cent earned less than 25 per cent of income in all 92 countries with data (United Nations, 2019a). In the case of Malaysia, the bottom 40% of population – the B40 – only get 16.4% of the national income share of wealth as in 2020 – not much has the wealth disparity gap closed since two decades ago, but instead, more inequality has accentuated :

The undeniable fact as to why many bumiputera had not attained parity despite +60 years of neo-liberal-enforced economic development is the existence of a new class of compradore capitalist. According to the UNDP 1997 Human Development Report, and the 2004 United Nations Human Development Report, Malaysia has the highest income disparity between the rich and poor in Southeast Asia, greater than that of Philippines, Thailand, Singapore, Vietnam and Indonesia.

5] DEBTS AND LABOUR EXPLOITATION

International debt repayment constitutes one of the forms of transfer of surplus produced by the countries of the South to the North – and of surplus produced by the workers of the South to the capitalists of their own countries and to those of the North. This has tended to increase the rate of labour force exploitation and labour conflicts in the South.

Underlining this trend, the developing countries and “emerging market” economies had transferred to their creditors an annual average of 3.68 percent of their GNP during the decade following the debt crisis (1980–89). In the past ten years (1997–2006), marked by a series of financial crises and a growing polarization of the capitalist world system, this transfer rose to 6.2 percent of GNP, (Notes: The figures are for 1980–2006. Calculation by the authors based on the data provided by the International Monetary Fund: IMF, 2006, World Economic Outlook Database, September, Washington D.C. It is the sum of annual values drawn from the line External Debt: Total Debt Service” from the group “Other Emerging Market and Developing Countries, http://www.imf.org.)

Whereas in 2012 low-income developing countries spent 3.3 per cent of their government revenues to meet external public debt obligations, this figure rose to 8.1 per cent in 2018, falling only slightly to an estimated 7.9 per cent in 2019. The squeeze on government revenues from service payments on external public (PPG) debt was particularly drastic in Sub-Saharan Africa, where this ratio jumped from a low point of 3.3 per cent in 2011 to an estimated 18.2 per cent in 2019, (monthlyreview online May 2021).

Almost one-fifth of government revenues in sub-Saharan Africa serviced external debts in 2019.

6] EXTERNAL TO INTERNAL DEBTS

Of ever increasing market integration and deregulation of capital movements, there has been a general transformation of debts to bonds on financial markets and a conversion of external debts into internal debts. This gradual evolution, which is still ongoing, hides some perverse effects, in particular that interest rates are often higher on internal debt.

It is more difficult towards a precise calculation of the size of the drain associated with this category of debts. All the more so because this transfer of surpluses from South to North continues to operate through different channels.

The disproportion of developing country debt, like the history of the monetary and financial international system, provides no indication of a solution to the current debt crisis if it is only the efforts and resources of these countries that are mobilized.

Economic, commercial, monetary and financial relations between the countries of the centre (North) and those of the periphery (the South) of the world capitalist system must be profoundly reorganized, according to new principles.

The dynamics of capitalism and capital accumulation based on the rationale of profit maximization and resource pillage towards underdevelopment of nations are injustice to humankind, (see capitalism and a reading list on Capitalism and Underdevelopment).

7] TRANSFER OF SURPLUS

The transfer of surplus from South to North continues to operate through a myriad of channels, such as the repatriation of profits on direct foreign investment, transfer pricing, price trading, profits on the revaluation of bonds recorded as portfolio investments in balance of payments, non-compliance currency transfer and other forms of unequal exchange.

These could be augmentedly completed from the operational processes of TNCs to seek low labour arbitrage and low-cost production processes (like lean to just-in-time and flexible production) and by competitive  strategic advantages with product differentiation in varied products with many features and multi-functionalities at various price structures in different marketspace.

By 2008, the top one hundred global corporations which had shifted their production foreign affiliates or subsidiaries accounted for 60 percent of their total assets and employment and more than 60 percent of their total sales. The foreign direct investment (FDI) to developing economies was US$694 billion in 2018 making up 58% global FDI share. By engaging in contractual relationships with partner firms but without equity involvement, mostly in the Global South, TNCs were generating about  US$2 trillion in sales in 2010 (UNCTAD, World Investment Report: Non-Equity Modes of International Production and Development  (Geneva: United Nations, 2011), 131).

8] DEBT SELF-PERPETUATING

It is an undeniable fact that national debt from loans do not contribute to financing economic development. Inevitable that the debt itself is increasingly to cover repayment of interests and capital. So it functions as a self-perpetuating mechanism of poverty aggravation, work overexploitation, and a block on development in the economies of the periphery of the capitalist world system, (see John Bellamy Foster, The Imperialist World, Monthly Review, May 2007).

This is due to developing countries (DC) very dependent on their respective commodities output and global prices. One can discern a correlation between the evolution of commodity prices and DCs’ external indebtedness.

From 1998 to 2003, a period that saw backflow of DCs’ capital towards the countries of the Global North, commodity prices were relatively low. From 2003-2004 on, those prices began a steep increase culminating in 2008. This phenomenon attracted investors and lenders from the Global North who were looking for countries offering guarantees based on their resources in commodities and their export revenues.

Thus, starting from 2008, there was a period of inflowing capital from countries of the North towards the DC. The governments and big private companies of the South were incited to take on more debt taking advantage of the super-cycle of commodities. Nevertheless there was a fall in 2009 due to the global crisis triggered by the major financial crisis of 2008 in the United States and Western Europe. Commodity prices rose again in 2010. In 2014 the cycle suddenly collapsed :

source: Eric Toussaint , Milan Rivié (April 2021)

The end of the ‘super cycle’ coincided with a steady drop in DCs’ foreign exchange reserves in months of import. Whereas countries dependent on commodities are advised to hold at least three months of import in foreign exchange reserve, low income countries are now well below this threshold. With the new fall in oil prices in 2020, the drop in export revenues, the higher amounts to be repaid from 2020 onward, a number of countries, particularly oil exporting countries, may not be able to repay their public external debt :

Global South’s foreign exchange reserves in months of import, source: Eric Toussaint , Milan Rivié (April 2021)

9] ODIOUS DEBTS

The encroached interests of the dominant capitalists of the countries in the Global North collude in close collaboration with the elites of peripheral countries. These alliances often produced complex situations, such as “odious” debts (illegitimate and/or illegal), the transformation of external debts into public debts – which can often be viewed as forms of “odious” debts – and “ecological debts.” Odious debts were contracted by local elites and used against the public interest, to finance sumptuous expenses, corruption, or repression of the working classes more often than not also inciting mounting community massacres and torture as briefly documented by Milan Rivié in Illicit Flows: Africa is the world’s main creditor (November 2020).

Illicit financial flows or financial transfers can be through:

i) “Tax and commercial IFFs”, which mostly consists of fraudulent issuing of invoices for products to be imported or exported, amounting to approximately 40 billion US$ per year;

ii) “illegal markets”, which are principally human trafficking and toxic waste;

iii) “Theft-type activities and financing of crime and terrorism”; and finally,

iv) IFFs linked to “corruption”

The amount of such colossal losses, US$89 billion per year according to the lowest estimates. This amounts to 3.7% of the continent’s GDP, and 25% of Egypt’s GDP, which is one of the three largest African economies alongside South African and Nigeria. It is also, almost equivalent to the total Official Development Aid, US$48 billion, and Foreign Direct Investment, US$54 billion, received by African countries per year :

adopted from Milan Rivié

However, the substitution of private debt by public debt was a way for countries to manage the debt crisis in favour of the local bourgeoisie in the clientel capitalism system as part of the ethnocapital rentier capitalism . When the USA decided to increase interest rates – in the hope of resolving their own crisis – many government of the peripheral capitalist countries at the beginning of the 1980s, nationalised a large part of the private external debt of the local bourgeoisie imposing responsibility for the cost of the operation on the population.

Furthermore, the debt also served to finance polluting activities of transnational companies (example: Mamut Mine, Sabah) which have resulted in dramatic destruction of the environment (project: Pan-Borneo Highway) and highly negative externalities, at national (case: Lynas) and international level.

An international law on debt needs to be enacted, supplemented, as necessary, by measures requiring TNCs and their local allies of ethnocapital to pay to the countries of the Global South reparations for their “ecological debts.”

The estimated annual value of ecosystem services is US$16–54 trillion, with an estimated average of US$33 trillion. US$33 trillion is 1.8 times the current global GNP.

10] IMMERISATION OF GLOBAL SOUTH

Increasing misery is existing across wide population spectrum in countries of the Global South, particularly in Africa. Between 1980 and 2006, more than US$675billion have been extorted to finance the debt service from the African continent, even though it is the poorest in the world.

As a yearly average during this period, this corresponds to $25 billion. By way of comparison, hardly more than half of this sum would be enough, according to the estimates of the UN Food and Agriculture Organization (FAO), to eradicate hunger, thanks to the provision of food rations corresponding to nutritional levels considered to be satisfactory to each poor inhabitant of the South.

Remember that according to the World Bank, there are over four billion poor people in the world, more than 850 million people still suffer today from malnutrition, and five million children die of starvation each year in the world. The wealth accumulated in the countries of the North is in part produced by exploitation of workers and destruction of nature in the countries of the South, (John Bellamy Foster, The Ecology of Destruction, Monthly Review, February 2007; The Conversation, What Karl Marx has to say about today’s environmental problems, June 2018; The Guardian, 9th September 2020).

11] HOUSEHOLDS DEBTS

Household debt also rose in emerging economies from 26 per cent of GDP in 2009 to 43 per cent by 2019. The bulk of the overall increase in lending to private non-financial sectors was lending to non-financial corporations in these economies, increasing from around 60 per cent of GDP just before the global financial crisis to over 100 per cent by 2017, where it is UNCTAD calculations, based on conversion to US dollars at market exchange rates, from BIS (2020) data.

Malaysia’s household debt-to-Gross Domestic Product (GDP) ratio surged to a new peak of 93.3% as at December 2020 from its previous record high of 87.5% in June 2020, according to Bank Negara Malaysia (BNM). “A concern over high household debt is that it may lead to a rapid deleveraging by households in the aftermath of a crisis, thus dampening or derailing economic recovery,” BNM warned in its Financial Stability Review for Second Half 2020 Report as released.

In the short term, many economists believe this high level of household debt-to-GDP ratio is manageable and do not pose that significant a risk to the country’s financial stability.

“From a macro perspective, it should not have a big impact on financial stability. Broadly, the risk from the household sector to the entire banking system remains manageable.

“BNM has taken pre-emptive measures and has the capacity to introduce further macroprudential tools if the financial environment requires it to,” said World Bank senior economist Shakira Teh Sharifuddin.

UOB (M) Bhd economist Julia Goh concurred, saying the high ratio is due to weaker GDP owing to the pandemic. It is also a result of government incentives to spur purchase of cars and property ownership.

“In a way, that has aided the recovery by supporting consumption amid a low interest rate environment. Other household financial stability indicators do not suggest higher risks so far given stable household financial asset-to-debt ratios and high excess savings.”

However, Institute for Democracy and Economic Affairs (IDEAS) chief executive officer Tricia Yeoh is sceptical of the lower-income households’ capacity to service their loans, and called on the government to reassess its policies to ensure economic recovery may be achieved without overstraining households.

Similarly, Socio-Economic Research Centre (SERC) executive director Lee Heng Guie highlighted the disproportionate impact of the pandemic on different levels of household income. “Clearly, there are segments of the household that are currently facing financial distress. My concern is for those who are highly geared, [who] will eventually go through a de-gearing process to rebuild their savings. This will in turn reduce consumption and curtail economic growth later,” he said.

However, there are three lingering concerns that need to be acknowledged, and be addressed:

i) If such high household debt levels persist, they may result in an unhealthy financial system that is fragile to future economic disruptions. Over the long term, if there is another downturn, and if the high level of household debt is not addressed, then definitely there is less room for monetary policy to take effect because households are already indebted to a high level.

The case of Malaysia: the bottom 40% of population – the B40 – only get 16.4% of the national income share of wealth as in 2020.

ii) There is an underlying issue on economic inequality, which, if not addressed, may pose systemic risk to the whole financial system.

iii) Then, there is the specter of income instability amongst the B40 group. Any shift in income, especially for lower-income households, will put them at risk of defaulting on these loans.

Malaysian household incomes are projected to fall by 12 per cent, which is est upimated amounted to RM$95 billion; and job losses are estimated to be of 2.4 million positions, 67% of which is unskilled labour, on the details that MIER released in 2020. Indeed, household debt – at nearly 83 per cent to gross domestic product – is among the highest in Asia.

12] PRIVATE EXTERNAL DEBTS

Concurrent with the above issues are the high levels of private external indebtedness that are of concern since they represent a large contingent liability on public sector finances, ultimately backed by international reserves held in the domestic economy. In the event of wide-spread private sector debt distress, governments will have little choice but to transfer the bulk of distressed private debt to public balance sheets.

The fragility of developing countries’ debt positions was further increased by accompanying changes to the ownership of long-term external public (PPG) debt. The share of PPG external debt of developing and transition governments owed to private creditors reached 62 per cent of the total in 2019, compared to around 20 per cent in the 1970s and 41 per cent in 2000. Its most volatile component, public bond finance, is clearly on the increase relative to financing through commercial bank loans and other private creditors. This reflects the growing reliance of developing country governments on refinancing their external debt obligations in international financial markets with strong speculative features rather than borrowing from official bilateral and multilateral creditors, which is generally more stable and in more favourable terms.

However, amid the pandemic most government revenues collapsed alongside economic activity, while private capital flows came to a sudden stop :

In addition to new loans from multilaterals, Group of Twenty (G20) creditors granted a debt moratorium to the world’s poorest countries. They have encouraged private lenders to follow suit—albeit with little success, IMF The Debt Pandemic

13] DEBT SERVICING

As cursory mentioned before, the rising external debt burden along with increased risk profiles of such debt shall translate into rising servicing costs. Debt service ratios are considered important indicators of a country’s debt sustainability.

In this sense, SDG indicator 17.4.1 measures “debt service as a proportion of exports of goods and services”. This indicator reflects a government’s ability to meet external creditor claims on the public sector through export revenues. A fall (increase) in this ratio can result from increased (reduced) export earnings, a reduction (increase) in debt servicing costs, or a combination of both. A persistent deterioration of this ratio signals an inability to generate enough foreign exchange income to meet external creditor obligations on a country’s PPG debt, and thus potential debt distress in the absence of multilateral support or effective sovereign debt restructuring.

It has been indicative that only high-income developing countries have maintained a stable ratio of external long-term PPG debt to export revenues of around two to four per cent in the last decade. This is largely due to their greater capacity to issue domestic public debt, with a view to avoid currency mismatches.

However, while greater reliance on local-currency denominated public debt reduces the vulnerability to exchange rate volatility, it frequently creates maturity mismatches.

In contrast, a marked increase of debt service ratios has been registered since 2012 across all other income categories: in middle-income countries this ratio rose from 3.1 per cent in 2012 to 6.9 per cent in 2019 and in low-income countries from 2.5 to 7.0 per cent. SIDS saw this ratio rise from a low point of 4.9 per cent in 2013 to 8.2 per cent in 2019. As these economies increasingly tapped into international capital markets, this reflects rising external public debt stocks since 2012 in a context of commodity price volatility, sluggish global economic growth and rising debt service, (UNCTAD 2020, World Investment Report 2020).

The Malaysia FEDERAL government debt and liabilities rose to RM$1.2569 trillion, or 87.3% of GDP, as at end-September 2020— up 7.5% in the first nine months of the year compared with RM$1.1692 trillion as at end-2019.  Indeed, country’s revenue is not rising as fast as the increase in operating expenditure that is more than 95% of revenue since 2008. Assuming the economy is set to expand by 7.5% in nominal terms during 2021 to RM$1,521.3bil,  Malaysia’s official debt to GDP and total debt to GDP is expected to rise to 64.1% and 77.9%, respectively in 2021, (The Star, 20 Mar 2021).

The debt service charges made up 14% (RM32.9 billion) of federal government revenue in 2019 and is estimated to take up 15.4% or RM34.95 billion of the government’s income in 2020. The amount is expected to rise even further to RM39 billion, or 16.5% of the government’s revenue for 2021, according to data in the Fiscal Outlook 2021 Report.

Even governments in high-income developing countries are often unable to issue long-term government securities at a sustainable rate of interest, yet they need to be able to pay off or roll over maturing short-term obligations.

14] REDEMPTION SCHEDULES

As a consequence of their rising indebtedness, developing countries face a wall of debt service repayments throughout the 2020s.

The redemption schedules for 2020 and 2021 already accumulated external public debt obligations alone amount to an estimated US$2 to 2.3 trillion in high-income developing countries and between US$700 billion to $1.1 trillion in low-and middle-income countries.

Point of view of Debtors as in 2018 adopted from Eric Toussaint and Milan Rivié 2020

The challenge posed by large debt overhangs must, however, be placed in the wider context of economic challenges arising from the COVID-19 crisis. While developed countries are putting together massive stabilisation packages to flatten both the pandemic curve and the curve of economic and financial crisis, this is not an option open to many developing economies, at least not at the required scale.

On one hand, developing countries cannot easily lock down their largely informal economies effectively without more people being affected by hunger rather than by illness. On the other, they face substantive limitations on their fiscal space to mount rescue packages comparable to those currently under way in developed economies.

Seriousness in case country Malaysia is that general government debt jumps to 76.0% of GDP in 2020 from 65.2% of GDP in 2019. The debt figures used by Fitch include officially reported “committed government guarantees” on loans, which are serviced by the government budget, and the 1MDB’s net debt, equivalent in September 2020 to 12.6% and 1.3% of GDP, respectively. On this basis, the debt burden is significantly higher than the medians of 59.2% and 52.7% for the ‘A’ and ‘BBB’ rating categories, respectively; we have been degraded to BBB by Fitch last year. Malaysia’s debt is close to 400% of revenue, around three times the peer median.

15] GOVERNMENT REVENUES SHARE

Moving beyond SDG indicator 17.4.1, the share of government revenues dedicated to servicing PPG debt rose sharply over recent years, particularly in the poorest developing economies.

Whereas in 2012 low-income developing countries spent 3.3 per cent of their government revenues to meet external public debt obligations, this figure rose to 8.1 per cent in 2018, falling only slightly to an estimated 7.9 per cent in 2019.

The squeeze on government revenues from service payments on external PPG debt was particularly drastic in Sub-Saharan Africa, where this ratio jumped from a low point of 3.3 per cent in 2011 to an estimated 18.2 per cent in 2019. In other words, governments in this region now spend, on average, almost one fifth of their revenues on servicing external public debt, see Eric Toussaint and Milan Rivié, An unsustainable burden of debt afflicts the peoples of Sub-Saharan Africa, Part 5 (May 2020).

This is of concern since low-income developing countries still rely predominantly on public financing to mobilise resources for structural transformation, yet also struggle the most with limited fiscal space given their shallow domestic financial and banking systems and limited options to refinance maturing debt obligations in the international financial markets.

that Malaysia’s total debt and liabilities as September 2020 include RM177 billion in committed government guarantees, 1Malaysia Development Bhd’s (1MDB) debt of RM32.3 billion (principal excluding interest costs) as well as RM173.3 billion in lease payments for public-private partnerships (PPP).

16] CENTRAL BANKS ROLES

To pay for imports and to meet external debt obligations, the vast majority of developing countries are heavily reliant on access to hard currencies, earned primarily through commodity and service exports, such as food, oil and tourism, or received through remittances, as well as access to further concessional and market-based borrowing.

Their central banks cannot act as lenders of last resort to their governments to the extent central banks in developed economies can without risking a large depreciation of their local currencies and its effects in terms of steep increases in the value of foreign-currency denominated debt.

This has the potential to unleash destructive inflationary pressures. But with volumes of international trade experiencing a sharp contraction, core commodity prices in free fall, tourism at a virtual standstill, remittances drying up and private capital outflows from developing countries reaching unprecedented levels in recent history, many developing economies are increasingly cut off from conventional sources of income when they need them most.

On the respondibilities of central banking post-Global Finance Crisis: READ former deputy governor of Bank Negara Malaysia

17] DECISIVE ACTIONS BY COUNTRIES

It is against this backdrop that already existing debt vulnerabilities and distress in developing countries require decisive action to avoid liquidity constraints turning into wide-spread insolvency crises.

Early multilateral initiatives to provide some breathing space to hard-hit developing countries include US$215 million in debt cancellation by the IMF of repayments due by the 25 poorest developing economies between May and October 2020, as well as the G20 “Debt service suspension initiative for poorest countries” between May and December 2020.

There are 73 primarily low-income developing countries are eligible under the above-stated initiative that could see the temporary suspension of up to around $18 billion in repayments on official bilateral debt. While these initiatives are welcome, they are unlikely to be sufficient in either scale or scope.

It has to be noted, however, new borrowing, for example in fast growing COVID-19 bond markets as well as through increased access to concessional multilateral lending, can help bridge immediate liquidity needs but it is bound to add to, rather than resolve, unsustainable external debt burdens. Well-designed debt relief – through a combination of temporary standstills with sovereign debt reprofiling and restructuring – will therefore be essential to address not only immediate liquidity pressures, but also to restore long-term external debt sustainability in many developing countries, not least with a post-COVID-19 view of achieving the 2030 Agenda for Sustainable Development, ( see UNCTAD (2020b) for more detail ).

Refer to Point #3 above regarding Malaysia PERMAI and the PEMERKASA stimulus packages

18] CADTM

Contrary to the dominant discourse, it is actually the case that the 54 African states finance developed countries and not the other way round. Similarly to the CADTM, the UNCTAD report also supports this claim. With IFFs rising to 836 billion dollars from 2010 to 2015, and an external debt of 770 billion dollars in 2018, “the continent [is] being labelled a ‘net creditor to the world’”.

Indeed up to 20 to 30 per cent of private wealth in many African countries is held in tax havens” and there were “almost 5,000 individuals from 41 African countries with assets of about $6.5 billion” in offshore bank accounts in 2015. In both cases, this type of major corruption is enabled by the (lack of) action of major powers, see various reports in the Tax Justice Network’s website:  https://fsi.taxjustice.net/en/; Fergus Shiel and Will Fitzgibbon, “About the Mauritius Leaks Investigation”, ICIJ, 23rd July 2019,  https://www.icij.org/investigations/mauritius-leaks/about-the-mauritius-leaks-investigation/ ; the ICIJ’s research:  https://www.icij.org/investigations/luanda-leaks/ and Marlène Panar, “Luanda Leaks, ou l’effondrement de l’empire dos Santos” in French or [Luanda Leaks and the unravelling of the dos Santos Empire], 21st January 2020, Le Point Afrique: https://www.lepoint.fr/afrique/luanda-leaks-ou-l-effondrement-de-l-empire-dos-santos-20-01-2020-2358701_3826.php (in French).

The former governor of Bank Negara Malaysia (BNM) case is exposed HERE, and explored further by theedgemarkets in the 8th. March 2020 issue.

The Committee for the Cancellation of Third World Debt (Comité pour l’Annulation de la Dette du Tiers Monde—CADTM), or Jubilee South, consider, with reason, that the developing countries have paid off their external debt to Northern creditors, in totality, and that it is the rich countries that effectively owe debts to the poorest countries.

19] IMF-WORLD BANK-PARIS CLUB

However, the countries at the centre of the world capitalist system and their multilateral monetary and financial institutions, above all the IMF, the World Bank, and the Paris Club – all have no interest in resolving the problem of external debt, because it represents a reliable means of keeping the countries of the South in perpetual dependence.

The structure of the external debt of developing countries from the point of view of creditors (rounded-off figures as provided by the World Bank on the indebtedness of developing countries in 2018) :

adopted from Eric Toussaint and Milan Rivié 2020

This comes about as an outcome of the Bretton Woods Agreement whose focus was to construct an international monetary order centered on the U.S. dollar. Other currencies were to be pegged to the US dollar, which was in turn pegged to gold, (see Cheng Enfu and Lu Baolin, Characteristics of Neoimperialism, Monthly Review, May 2021).

The U.S. dollar has played the prominent role in world currency, since replacing the British sterling pound, thus designating the U.S. a dominant global positioning. As such, the U.S. dollar makes up 70 percent of global currency reserves, accounting for 68 percent of international trade settlements, 80 percent of foreign exchange transactions, and 90 percent of international banking transactions. Owing to this financial dominance, the U.S. dollar has also become the internationally recognized reserve currency and trade settlement currency.

Often, serious financial hardship for a number of countries is dependent on revenues from oil, agriculture or minerals. This factor has been aggravated by the devaluation of currencies of countries from the South against the US dollar, see Eric Toussaint and Milan Rivié, Developing countries in the stranglehold of debt, Part 3 (April 2020).

The United States can also obtain international seigniorage by exporting U.S. dollars. She can reduce its foreign debt by depreciating the U.S. dollar or assets that are priced in U.S. dollars. The hegemony of the U.S. dollar has also caused the transfer of wealth from debtor countries to creditor countries. This would, in fact, mean that poor countries would subsidize the rich.

20] NEOLIBERALISM’s NEO-IMPERIALISM

Neoimperialism is monopolistic financial capitalism established by large transborder multinationals whose production and capital are “concentrated into fewer and fewer hands.” (see John Bellamy Foster, Robert W. McChesney, and R. Jamil Jonna, “Monopoly and Competition in Twenty-First Century Capitalism,” Monthly Review 62, no. 11, 2011 :1).

Neo-Imperialism monopolizes almost all sources of raw materials, scientific and technological talent, and skilled physical labour in all fields, controlling the transportation hubs and infrastructural platforms by various modes and means of production – and by owning, controlling and dominating capital, global financial functions and associated derivatives and information technologies through vast cultural and military shareholding systems, it has

indebted all poverty poors of the world


more Malaysian Manuscripts available HERE


Standard

UNDERDEVELOPMENT UNDER MONOPOLY-CAPITALISM

1] INTRODUCTION

Incorporating Lenin’s concepts of imperialism and international class conflict into the theory of economic growth and stagnation, the Global South, predominantly low developing countries (LDCs) were in the clutch of Global North Western economic and political domination, especially during the colonial period.

Capitalism arose not through the growth of small competitive firms at home-country but through the transfer from abroad of advanced monopolistic businesses with monopoly-capital attachment and or alignment. When capitalism took hold, the bourgeoisie (the corporate capital and compradore capitalists) in country, seeked allies among other classes, initially with monopoly-capitalism in Global North, and post-1957 increasingly adopted an economic nationalism construct to engender a cohort of ethnocratic kleptocrates, and subsequently tapped upon emerging rise of the ethnocapital clientel capitalism class.

2] FROM NEOLIBERAL POINTS

What often not stated that economic development in underdeveloped countries is profoundly goodness to the dominant interests in the advanced capitalist countries. The “backwardness” of the developing world is not infrequently hidden as the rich hinterland of the highly developed Global North capitalist West to be “developed”, but exploited.

Development discipline tends to frame within the bounds of national territorial boundaries of a nation-state. The primary theories then regard development based on stages of growth, diffusionism, and modernization-developmentalist with paradigm’s proponents from Rostow (1960), Pye (1962), Parsons (1964) to Hoselitz (1960), Lerner (1965), and McClelland (1967) contending that socio-economic progress (or the lack of it) was due to the presence (or absence) of resource, institutional or psychological-sociological cultural ingredients in each respective nation-state that were necessary for development to occur. Early development understanding posits an ideal developed society couched on a Western value framework.

We have the ‘Washington Consensus’, first articulated by World Bank economist John Williamson, focusing on a neo-liberalization thrust in trade, investment and the financial sector and the deregulation and privatization of nationalized industries. Often the conditionalities are attached without due regard for the borrower countries’ individual resulting in the loss of a state’s authority to govern its own economy as national economic policies are predetermined under The World Bank and its International Monetary Fund packages. These “packages” have negative social outcomes such as reduced investment in public health and education, but still have sufficient capital expenditure beneficial to local compradors, industrial-capitalists and later ruling regimes’ ethnocapital as well as definitely monopoly-capitalists globally.

We may also can have a premise where a country is poor because it was previously so poor that it could not save and invest as once justified by Jeffrey Sachs (2005) primarily ‘Poverty itself is the cause of economic stagnation.’

But the “low saving rate” whatever accumulated surplus had already expropated by colonial masters, (see Amin and Calwell; Utsa Patnaik and Prabhat Patnaik; Samir Amin; Andrè Gunter Frank)

Sach’s premise followed closely to the vicious circle theory as presented by Ragnar Nurkse in his 1953 book- The Problems of Capital Formation in Underdeveloped Countries – where poverty perpetuates itself in mutually reinforcing vicious circles on both the supply and demand sides. In fact, low per capita income is both the cause and the effect of poverty whence, however, through settlement colonialism, and later within neo-colonialism, the wealth of nations had been expropriated many times again and again.

On the other had, Rosenstein-Rodan was of the opinion that a major indivisibility lies in infrastructure, such as power, transport and communications. This basic social capital should reduce costs to other industries. The IBRD (the former World Bank’s International Bank for Reconstruction and Development) encouraged a country like Malaysia to borrow large loans to construct these high-cost infrastructure, tied to “packages”, resulting to consequent indebtedness and a stagnant economy when the Asian Financial Crisis and Global Financial Crisis came visitings.

Then, we have Hischman’s view that low-income countries need a development strategy that spurs invest­ment decisions. He suggests that since physical resources and managerial skills and abilities are scarce in LDCs, a big push is sensible only in strategically selected industries within the economy. Growth is then likely to spread from one sector to another (similar to Rostow’s concept of leading and lagging sectors); thus, Malaysia went for industrialization, but with poor labour employment by TNCs, labour alienation and union bustings and an under-developed and unsettled peasantry.

According to Hirschman, agriculture does not necessarily would stimulate linkage formation so directly as other industries. However, it is not that accurate to say that exertion in Malaysia where large agrobusiness Big Farms are benefitting Caterpillar and John Deere. In the process, envisaged in the midst of the Vietnam war, the FELDA (Federal Land Development Authority) schemes is a corridor sanitarian to corral rural Malay communities with modern built-in infrastructure –  with clinics, schools, roads and bridges – ensuring subsistence dependence loyalty to the ruling class and a transnational corporation domain that is technological-based in FTZs and EFTZs to mop-up precarious labor (see Precarious Labor in Industrialization Capitalism and Precarious Labour in a Digitalised Economy; refer to Hao Qi, (Sept 2019), “Semi-proletarianization in a Dual Economy: the Case of China”, Review of Radical Political Economics, to forestall possible Urban-Agrarian collaboration and cooperation for revolutionary changes towards a new political economy in Malaysia.

3] NEO-IMPERIALISM UNDER MONOPOLY-CAPITALISM

That what is widely referred to as neoliberal globalization in the twenty-first century is in fact a historical product of the shift to global monopoly-finance capital or what Samir Amin calls the imperialism of “generalized-monopoly capitalism.”

Since the 1974-1975 recession, there was a growth rate slowdown in advanced capitalist economies with hurtful economic effects on the poorest countries. Scouting for wider markets to sustain capitalism, a proliferation of corporations begins setting up assembly lines across borders in different nations, especially the developing countries – the Global South – where in 2010, more than half of all foreign direct investment (FDI) went to third world and transition economies. With this strategic positioning in place, and world production dominated by a relatively few transnational corporations (TNC) exercising considerable monopoly power over states and labour, the migration towards the international concentration of capital clearly reflected on the work of Lenin (Imperialism, the Highest Stage of Capitalism, New York: International Publishers, 1939) and, on the other hand, confirms Amin’s imperialism of generalized-monopoly capitalism and Emmanuel’s  unequal exchange under Neo-Imperialism.

Jason Hickel, Dylan Sullivan and Huzaifa Zoomkawala contended in the New Political Economy published online: 30 Mar 2021 – that wealth drain from the Global South remains a significant feature of the world economy in the post-colonial era; rich countries continue to rely on imperial forms of appropriation to sustain their high levels of income and consumption. The Global North appropriated from the Global South commodities worth US$2.2 trillion in Northern prices that are enough to end extreme poverty 15 times over. Over the 1960–2018 period studied, the value drain from the Global South totalled US$62 trillion (constant 2011 dollars), or US$152 trillion when accounting for the Global South countries’ lost growth. Indeed, it is found that the appropriation through unequal exchange represents up to 7% of Global North’s GDP and 9% of Global South GDP.

During this era in imperialism of generalized-monopoly capitalism, there is a shift of manufacturing industry from the Global North to the Global South. In 1980 the share of world industrial employment of developing countries had risen to 52 percent; by 2012 this had increased to 83 percent. By 2013, 61 percent of the total worldwide inward flow of foreign direct investment (FDI) was in developing and transitional economies, up from 33 percent in 2006 and 51 percent in 2010.

Thus, by the twenty-first century imperialism is thus taking on a new, more developed phase related to the globalization of production and finance.

4] THE MARXISM PERSPECTIVE

The disparity in wealth-sharing can be perceived in another frame. A part of the imperialist rent remains in the peripheral country and is not transferred to the center, but constitutes rather a payment to local ruling classes for their roles in the globalization game. About $21 trillion of this global tribute, meanwhile, is currently parked abroad in tax-haven islands, “the fortified refuge of Big Finance”,  see  International Consortium of Investigative Journalists on their Fin-Tech files, and the Guardian,  “£13tn Hoard Hidden from Taxman by Global Elite” July 21, 2012, and Nicholas Shaxson, Treasure Islands (London: Palgrave Macmillan, 2011), 7.

Marx (1818-83) had professed that the capitalist system would – in the initial stage grow due to increased profit (surplus value which was the result of exploitation of labour) – but would also pro­vide funds for accumulation. Owing to the fact that since wages were pegged at the subsistence level, due to the existence of a huge reserve army of unemployed, the capitalists would suffer from a realisation crisis. They would not be able to realise the profits embodied in already produced goods. And, according to Marx, the under consumption of the masses is the root cause of all crises.

Inevitably, Neo-Imperial domain of monopoly-capitalism in international concentration of capital would give birth to the introduction of international monopoly-finance capital that ensues the emergence of financialization capitalism (see John Bellamy Foster, The Financialization of Accumulation, Monthly Review vol:62, issue 05 October 2010). Financialization capitalism becomes prominent because the TNCs are unable to find sufficient investment outlets for their huge economic surpluses from production, increasingly turn to speculation within the global financial sphere, (see John Bellamy Foster and Fred Magdoff, The Great Financial Crisis (New York: Monthly Review Press, 2009).

This historical trend is basically following the trend in the capitalism route to a pathway from monopoly-capitalism to neo-imperialism:

Firstly, with a slowing down of the overall rate of growth among developed countries in Global North, followed by secondly, the internationalisation of monopolistic transnational corporations (TNCs) especially crossing borders to third world countries in the Global South, and then the introduction of, and emergence in, the “capital accumulation process” or financialization capitalism

5] TOWARDS A SOCIALISM HORIZON

If one were to take on the classical theory of David Ricardo (1772-1823), then a pessimistic view about the possibility of sustained economic growth would also surface. For Ricardo, who expressed that with little continu­ing technical progress, growth was limited by scarcity of land. The major tenet of Ricardo’s underlying understanding lies with the law of diminishing returns.

The central theme in the diminishing returns concept is that owing to population growth and a fixed supply of land would threaten economic growth. Ricardo believed that only technical change or improved production techniques (which might not likely to happen) to avert, possibly temporarily, the operation of the law of di­minishing returns. Therefore, increasing capital was seen as the only way to offset this long-run threat.

However, any fall in the rate of capital accumulation would lead to eventual stagnation. Ricardian stagnation might result in a Marxian scenario, in which wages and investment would be maintained only if property were confiscated by society and payments to private capitalists and landlords stopped.

Marx, in fact, made certain predictions about the growth, maturity and stagnation of capital­ism. He predicted that the capitalist system would ultimately collapse for want of markets and would yield place to socialism.

Unfortunately, history has not obliged Marx. The year 1989 saw the collapse of socialism (especially in erstwhile USSR and its satellite countries) and with it the abandonment of the centralised planning system and the emergence of newborn post-socialist countries.

All these countries have embraced the market system which is now thought to be a more efficient mecha­nism for solving society’s economic problems, promoting faster economic growth and improv­ing the living standards of the people.

That is, until the financial crisis of 2007–2008, also known as the Global Financial Crisis (GFC 2007/8), that was of such a severe worldwide economic crisis until the present COVID-19 recession, that many economists considered this Ecological-Epidemiological-Economic crisis to be the most serious financial crisis since the Great Depression.

China, on the other hand, went the other way in 1989, when she went for market opening in terms of trade, but was much more cautious in terms of capital account liberalisation, adopting a strong developmental state and gradualism in policy implementation.

Between authoritarianism and the growing role of government under the post-war Keynesian philosophy, the neo-liberal ideology had idolised free markets, but ignored (politically) the growing negative effects of social inequality, climate change, human identity crisis in the face of insecurities from technological disruption, massive human migration and geopolitical rivalries as even Tan Sri Andrew Sheng, formerly of World Bank, Hong Kong Monetary Authority and Bank Negara Malaysia, now agreed.

The only way out of the impasse may be a proletariat and peasant revolution, say expropriating (FELDA) land and (ethnocractic) capital, and establishing a new regime based on collective effort, sharing of distributed wealth and the creed of the pre­dominance of interests of society over the interests of a selected ethnocapital few.


More MALAYSIAN MANUSCRIPTS


Standard

UNEQUAL EXCHANGE UNDER NEO-IMPERIALISM

Imperialism never ended – it just changed form

1] INTRODUCTION

A paper in the New Political Economy (NPE 2021 henceforth referred) published online: 30 Mar 2021 Jason Hickel, Dylan Sullivan and Huzaifa Zoomkawala contended that wealth drain from the Global South remains a significant feature of the world economy in the post-colonial era; rich countries continue to rely on imperial forms of appropriation to sustain their high levels of income and consumption.

The researcher-authors discover that the Global North appropriated from the Global South commodities worth US$2.2 trillion in Northern prices that are enough to end extreme poverty 15 times over. Over the 1960–2018 period studied, the value drain from the Global South totalled US$62 trillion (constant 2011 dollars), or UD$152 trillion when accounting for the Global South countries’ lost growth. Indeed, it is found that the appropriation through unequal exchange represents up to 7% of Global North’s GDP and 9% of Global South GDP.

Net appropriation occurs because prices are extremely low in the Global South averaging one-fifth of Global North workers’ wages, see TNC Labour Exploitation MANUSCRIPT. Samir Amin and Arghiri Emmanuel had described this as a “hidden transfer of value” from the Global South to sustain high levels of income and consumption in the Global North.

Indeed, according to the NPE 2021 authors, the Global South losses even outstrip foreign aids by a huge margin, for instance, every dollar of aid to the developing countries would they lose US$14 through unequal exchange rates, transfer pricing, price trading, illicit financial outflows from corruption, tax evasion, profit repatriation or money laundering through smuggling.

2] NEO-IMPERIALISM WITH MONOPOLY CAPITAL STRONGHOLDS

Even before the Federation of Malaya gained independence, the International Bank for Reconstruction and Development (IBRD) Mission of 1954, had already schemed definitive proposals to propel the country’s industrialization program towards a neo-imperialism orbit. Its platform’s The Report of the Industrial Development Working Party, Kuala Lumpur, 1957 bound succeeding ruling regimes to monopoly-capitalism till today.

That enactment in August 1958 gave tax incentives to pioneer industries and permitted assurances to remit profits and capital, and against nationalization to foreign investors. The Foreign Investments Guarantee Agreement provides protection against the risk of expropriation without adequate compensation and non-convertibility of profits; this Agreement was signed with USA, Germany, Canada and The Netherlands. Further, double-tax agreements have been signed with the United Kingdom, Japan, Singapore, Sweden, Norway and Denmark.

IBRD was the original World Bank institution where it works closely with the rest of the World Bank Group to help ostensibly developing countries reduce poverty, promote economic growth, and build prosperity. However, there are often ‘conditionalities’ imposed on borrower countries where loans are based on what is termed the ‘Washington Consensus’, focusing on a neo-liberalization thrust in trade, investment and the financial sector and the deregulation and privatization of nationalized industries. Often the conditionalities are attached without due regard for the borrower countries’ individual resulting in the loss of a state’s authority to govern its own economy as national economic policies are predetermined under The World Bank and its International Monetary Fund packages, and where most developing countries hold little voting power. These “packages” have also been associated with negative social outcomes such as reduced investment in public health and education, but still have sufficient capital expenditure beneficial to local compradors, industrial-capitalists and later ruling regimes’ ethnocapital as well as monopoly-capitalists globally.

As expressed in NPE 2021, during the 1980s and 1990s, IMF structural adjustment programmes cut public sector wages and employment, while rolling back labour rights and other protective regulations that cheapened labour and resources immensely. Presently, all poor countries are structurally dependent on foreign investment but have to compete with one another “to offer cheap labour and resources in order to please the barons of international finance”.

There is no lack of investments in the manufacturing sector in the case of Malaysia. In 1957, 60% of share capital was then owned by transnational corporations (TNCs). There was a growth of 12% per annum by value added in manufacturing, but direct employment in the manufacturing sector grew less than 9% annually. The predominantly inward-oriented industrialization strategy catered the ruling class consumption and bourgeois middle income consumers. The protection and incentive schemes in the pioneer industry entrenched industrial enclaves and extended monopoly-capitalists exploitation process thereon and henceforth.

3] MONOPOLY-CAPITALISM EXPLOITATION

Monopoly-capitalist exploitation in the manufacturing sector is empirically demonstrated in the following findings. British firms, for example, which constituted 1% of the manufacturing establishment but 19% of the total sale, hired only 8% of the employees in the manufacturing sector; American firms constituted 0.2% of the manufacturing establishment with 16 firms, took 5% of the sale, but only 1.1% of workers hired, (Federation of Malaysia, Census of Manufacturing Industries, West Malaysia 1958, p.38).

An analysis of these limited companies’ reinvestment rates found that Japanese firms had a low 10%, American firms were. 11%, British 14% and Singapore 22%, (Charles Hirschman, Ownership and Control in the Manufacturing Sector in West Malaysia, UMBC Economic Review, United Malayan Banking Corporation, Kuala Lumpur, Vol.7 No.1, 1971, p.26).

Hence, TNCs invested sparingly, employed lowly, tech transfer minimally, but produced and profited highly.

Indeed, in 1980, for example, the average profit rates on US direct investment abroad in developing countries were about 30% where the profit equals income plus fees and royalties as percentage of total investment, (as cited from Robin Broad, identifiable as the U.S. Department of Commerce computer print-outs, Unequal Alliance: The World Bank, the International Monetary Fund and the Philippines, University of California Press, 1988).

The outflow of profits and capital gushes unceasingly since the implementation of tax exemptions and other favorable pioneer status inducements. For example, the tax reliefs on profit, amounting to 40%, and dividends paid out of profits, under the 1958 Pioneer Industries Ordinance come at a time when the country’s development and social expenditure needs are growing, but the protection and incentive systems have eroded national revenues. The introduction of the Investment Incentives (Amendment) Act in 1971 accelerated the rate of capital exploitation and capital repatriation processes. By this legislation, manufacturers of electronics and electrical companies can claim 10 years of tax relief; TNCs do not request the maximum period as this entails employing more personnel as a condition under this claim.

Further, companies granted investment tax credits are able to deduct from their taxable incomes a sum not less than 25% of capital expenditure incurred on factory, building or machinery. The contradictions in Malaysia’s industrialization program are clear: on one hand, there is a policy to increase employment through labor-intensive industries, but on the other hand, there is a concurrent incentive scheme which favors a capital-intensive strategy.

There is even a capital allowance scheme for building and plant expenditures incurred, and when incorporated with the accelerated depreciation allowance incentive, companies will virtually have 90% of eligible capital expenditure completely written off within 5 years.

4] THE UNEQUAL EXCHANGE INTERMEDIARIES

The perpetuation of Neo-Imperialism would not, and cannot come about if the pervasive middlemen and the networks of rent-seeking cohorts in the plantation, mining, commerce sectors were dismantled.

However, the ownership and control have not changed substantially, and though local capitalists and the intermediaries are not necessarily those of Chinese middlemen or Indian compradors nowadays, but kleptocrats that serve as the most obvious link in an exploitative economic system. Owing to the imposed ethnocentric nature of economic activities, any present economic discourse has often tended to deflect rakyat2 attention and hostility away from those more powerful and central actors that are looting the country’s tills, (see STORM 2013: Illicit Capital, Illegal Trade and Inequality – Kleptocracy in Malaysia).

The emergence, and roles, of ethnocapital have evolved since independence gained, and with the New Economic Policy (NEP) implemented has only reconstructed the political process of economic nationalism.

Historically, the country has been a place where many, and large, fortunes were amassed. Whereas the majority of businesses built during the prewar period were found in the tin and rubber industries that comprised illustrious family firms built by Low Yat, Loke Yew, Chong Yoke Choy, H.S. Lee, Tan Chay Yan and Lau Pak Khuan who colluded with colonial British plantation interests to build their empires, the 1980s “new money-capital” entities like YTL Corp’s Yeoh Tiong Lay, Berjaya’s Vincent Tan, Genting’s Lim Goh Tong, Sunway’s Jeffrey Cheah, Lion’s William Cheng and the Ananda Krishnan groups and business stables attempted the forging of more Sino-Indo-Malay corporations, that is, a co-opetition strategy whereby Chinese and Indian capitals can compete as well as co-operate with Malay interests. Those Kuoks, Tehs and Queks were the pioneers in the sugar and palm oil, property and banking sectors during the British Empire, whereas the YTLs’ and Berjayas’ and Annans’ were maintained and retained by transnational connections in the post-independence neo-colonialism period, and the GLCs (government-linked companies) and GLIC (government-linked investment corporations) formulated were sustained with, and by, various ethnocracy kleptocratic regimes ever since.

What Gomez and Saravanamuttu in The New Economic Policy in Malaysia Affirmative Action, Ethnic Inequalities and Social Justice, ISEAS 2013) had indicated is that economic situations have worsened after the New Economic Policy (NEP) was implemented. They faulted upon the preferences designed to encourage Bumiputera entrepreneurship were sadly disproportionately utilized by members of the targeted group in urban and the more prosperous rural areas. The present policies of protecting Malay special rights are often regarded as a mere pretence intended to prevent bold and modern economic activities in rural society, by suceeding ruling regimes, following the colonial practice of divide and rule.

Indeed, the issues are relating to the concentration of economic power (as driven by a stronghold of clientelism) and the ensuring political clientel relationship where ruling elites in the United Malay National Organisation (UMNO) had aligned with economic oligarchs in accepting rentier capitalism to sustain their hold on power. They adopt this clientelism as solicitations for votes at the grassroots level, allowing ruling elites the party patronage and political power to “effectively partisanizing them and ensuring ground-level officials with whom most voters interacted with ……are political party loyalists” (Weiss, 2020), resulting in the skewed distribution of profits by political stakeholders and the stark inequality of wealth permeating in the country (Khalid 2019).

There is every reason to say that patronage position is ever in the prescence of ruling elites and the political power that oozes dominating control therefrom. Indeed, ruling elites are the biggest “owners” of divisional-level of UMNO constituency places with the office-bearing posts that defined political positioning posts with the ensuing power distributing spoils that emit therefrom. The ownership of ruling regime’s divisional-level [place], by situating in a office-bearing [position], with the control of vested distributing [power] spoil elements is, thus, explicit.

Now with the advent of infrastructural platforms, the role of ethnocapital has changed from managing physical assets in a GLC to that as intermediaries to IT service providers. Not only the ecosystem responsibilities have enlarged, the asset management is huge, too.

JENDELA as part of the 12th Malaysia Plan (2021-2025) with RM$21 billion of which 40 per cent is derived from Malaysian Communications and Multimedia Commission (Universal Service Provision (USP) funds with the remaining 60 per cent to be funded by industry players; tender for infrastructure works at 1,661 sites involving an investment value of RM4.6 billion under JENDELA, closed on March 31, 2021, during a time of when capitalism is colliding into an Ecological-Epidemiological-Economic crisis.

In 2021, both the telecommunications industry and MCMC will be working together to track the migration from 3G to 4G, as Jendela aims to build a solid foundation through the optimisation of the 4G network and fiberising of premises in Malaysia , besides increasing mobile broadband speeds from 25Mbps to 35Mbps and enabling up to 7.5 million premises to access gigabit speeds with fixed broadband services.

5] CONCLUSION

i) With 1990s’ unrestricted movement of international finance capital, public sector enterprises or government-link companies (GLCs) increasingly are subjected under the bound of financialization capitalism. The metropolitan capital-as-finance, expressed by Patnaik, gets control over Third World resources and enterprises to see the rise to international finance capital in league with the local neocomprador class becoming crony capitalism through the force of accumulation as articulated by Samir Amin (2019) in The New Imperialist Structure, Monthly Review, July 01, 2019. Anchored upon a capital-market system, this leads to the emergence to, and the pervasion of, financialization capitalism in Malaysia, and the consequence of continuance of indebting the nation:

ii) According to Emmanuel’s premise is that , unequal exchange in the ‘strict sense’ characterises the trade rela­tion between the centre and periphery whereby ‘the inequality of wages as such, all other things being equal, is alone the cause of the inequality of exchange.’

As a corollary, Emmanuel had argued that by transferring through non-equivalent exchange, a large part of its surplus to the rich coun­tries, the periphery deprives itself of the means of accumulation and growth.”  Thus, an impor­tant implication of Emmanuel’s theory is that a widening wage gap leads to a deterioration of the periphery’s terms of trade, and a subsequent reduction in its rate of economic growth, see Emmanuel’s formulation on his theory.

A glaring scenario is presented in the case of Malaysia tied to the financialization capitalism of, and closely connected to, monopoly-capital in the Global North with the dire aftermath repercussions from the Asia Financial Crisis 1997 and the Global Financial Crisis 2008 era (see Post-1997 Political Economy and Underdevelopment under Monopoly-capitalism, May 2021).

The Stagnated Economy, Sudhdave 2020

iii) Applied, there is a growing centralisation of political and eonomic power in the Office of the Prime Minister and the Minister of Finance with a confluence of influence of the state over the GLCs that have the concentration of capital and accumulation of capital as Gomez laid out in Minister of Finance Incorporated: Ownership and Control of Corporate Malaysia :

The web of the Prime Minister Office that is linked to the Prime Minister Economics Affair controlling government corporations, registered companies, trust and saving funds, cooperatives, state authorities, research and development departments The Political Economy of Malaysia

iv) And more importantly, by offering higher dividend returns, cooperating closely with those local corporate capital that have connections to Global North monopoly capitalists and through internationalising  their operations, they successfully link up electrical and electronic small manufacturing enterprises (SME) with products assembly, supplies and logistics competitiveness into the Global North supply chains where an exemplary entity can be seen in the pharmaceutical industry at times of a pandemic in Pharmaniaga.

v) TM, similarly, has the franchised monopoly as a GLC, owning the national digital telecommunications sector and controlling upstream and downstream the supply chain. With the unveiling of the Malaysia Digital Economy Blueprint (MyDigital) on 19th. February 2021, TM will be given relevant spectrum to own, execute and manage the 5G infrastructure.

Most investment analysts agree that Telekom Malaysia Bhd (TM) is a key beneficiary given its global network of over 20 submarine cable systems and over 560,000km of fibre network across Malaysia. “We raise our FY20-FY22 earnings forecasts for TM by 4% to 16% after factoring in higher data and internet revenue”, so said PublicInvest. (theedgemalaysia, 2021).

vi) The hardening of corporate capital monopoly tied to external resources sourcing from monopoly-capital only accentuate the depth of Neo-Imperialism penetration into the country, even in midst of a Covid19 pandemic ;

TM together with Microsoft, Google and Amazon as cloud service providers (CSPs) have been given conditional approval by the government to manage and build hyperscale data centres and cloud services for the public sector. TM, as the only home-based CSP, stands to benefit from the public sector’s recurring and growing revenue base, said Kenanga Research; the CSPs will total between RM12 billion and RM15 billion over the next five years. Strong fiber adoption from the national digital network (Jendela) project, net additions for Unifi and overall a higher growth for wholesale and data revenues are expected to lift Telekom Malaysia Bhd

vii) On those above-mentioned situational scenarios, what we have, according to Fitch Solutions, is that due to potential lack of transparency because the JENDELA rollout is through a Special Purpose Vehicle, there are three crony ICT companies being appointed as management service providers (MSP) whereby ethnocapital maintains and tightens ownership and control on new enterprise ventures.

viii) At a wider perspective is the spectre of unequal exchanges between Global North’s infrastructural platforms and Global South’s information technologies and information systems dependency :

In 2013 Apple had about 80,000 employees worldwide, Google around 40,000, and Facebook about 4,600; when Facebook purchased WhatsApp – for US$19 billion – it had only 55 employees. In fact, all these industrial-tech models eliminated jobs (by sacking people directly or by replacing or residening offshoring from their Global North businesses), and through the circuitry in monopoly-capital (Foster 2000; 2014; 2020) most of the jobs directly created predominatly in the Global South are call-centres, cloud-servers, systems integrators, routers distributors. [To read the job of a Google contractual worker, Fortune]

Within the two decades before the end of the millennium, digital monopolies have overtaken the older oil, automobile and financial monopolies in terms of capital capitalisation. Computers, networks, data centres and servers become the new technologies of capitalism roaming globally: the emergence of a digital system basing on gigantic infrastructural platforms becomes a reality for many bionic businesses, (BCG, Is Your Technology Ready for the New Digital Reality?Boston Consultancy Group, May 08, 2020, and its The Bionic Company).

ix) Referring to NPE 2021, the periphery tends to transfer surplus through trade because its rate of surplus value is higher than the world average due to an international wage gap, which favours workers in the centre. Therefore, even if the organic composites of capital are equalised, unequal exchange results from the existence of a wage gap between the centre and the periphery, and within a nation the disparity in wealth distribution :

According to the UNDP 1997 Human Development Report, and the 2004 United Nations Human Development Report, Malaysia has the highest income disparity between the rich and poor in Southeast Asia, greater than that of Philippines, Thailand, Singapore, Vietnam and Indonesia.

It creates, therefore, a permanent tendency of lagged development in the Global South and a subsidized, superannuated Global North, (see ISR issue 107).

Labour, under an e-commerce environment, becomes digital-dehumanised workers where they are mere inputs in an Azeem Azhar’s AI interfacing intermediaries loop as conduits to big data storage and retrieval. A gig-worker daily experience and personal assets are exposed to financialisation or value extraction.

Thirdly, the USA tech-venture capital bloc’s reducing capital gains taxes in 1978 from 50% to 28% became known as the Silicon Valley model, now emulated all over the world (Marxist Sociology April 2021) with mitigated effect on “contingent workers”, (Fortune 2019). For Global North workers, today’s real average wage (that is, the wage after accounting for inflation) in USA has about the same purchasing power it did 40 years ago; and, what wage gains there have been have mostly flowed to the highest-paid tier of workers, (PewResearch 2018) :

Noam Chomsky once stated on the US economy structure “what you find is that $47 trillion were taken from the bottom 90%, the middle class and the working class, and put in the hands of the top 10%. But if you look closely, it’s a fraction of the top 10% which takes the greatest wealth. Since Reagan, they have doubled their ownership of society’s wealth from 10% to 20%.” 

The consequential manipulation of such raw data into timely, accurate, relevant and complete information – by infrastructural capitalism platforms that are so overwhelmingly powerful in exploiting not only surplus value of labour but in the regal accumulation of capital relentlessly, too, (Social EuropeGig Workers Guinea Pigs of the New World of Work, February, 2021, and also see Foundation for European Progressive StudiesGoverning Online Gatekeepers: Taking Power Seriously, 2021).

x) Through the ownership and control of information, this emergent class dominates not only labour but digital capital, too. Capital accumulation permeates the entire production chain but through soft elements in the ownership of patents, copyrights, brands and logistical systems – typically known as the Intellectual Property Rights -impoverishing the poors but enrich the bourgeoisie class by way of financialization capitalism that digitally routed neo-imperialism onto a refreshed monopoly-capital commodity supply chain pathway:

Instead of exerting downward pressure in the middle of the curve – the part on processes of production – intellectual monopoly has inadvertently points to an upward pressure at both ends of the smiley curve where the control over intangible assets (like R&D and design, and e-commerce marketing and post-sales interfaces) is most concentrated.

xi) One can say that this upward pressure on both left and right sides of the curve is a resultant outcome from dynamics arising from the growing role of intangible assets in the value chain processes, and also from tighter Intellectual Property Rights. This means that the market power of leading firms – the product/service initiators or front-runners – is often enhanced by intellectual monopoly endorsement which is fueled on one part by the dynamic advantages arising from global value chains network externalities, and on the other side, by the increasing returns on intangibles and legally-enforced proprietary control over standards, technologies and brands, (UNCTADThe Digital Economy Report 2019: Value Creation and Capture: Implications for Developing Countries; Jomo 2020; Jomo 2021).

xii) There is a new battle on unequal exchange – not merely or only in the Production-exchange-Consumption model in physical goods – but in the soft digital arena presence in the infrastructural horizon: Digital generation-exchange-Usage which is still sheer expropriation and surely exploitative.

The implications for third world countries are that due to the monopoly-capital competition dynamics in the Global North, developing-country platforms that are trying to scale up typically face an uphill battle. The dominance of global digital platforms, their control of data, as well as their capacity to create and capture the ensuing value, tend to further accentuate concentration and consolidation rather than reduce inequalities between and within countries.

Secondly, in the global “data value chain”, many countries are already entrenched in subordinate positions, with value and data being concentrated in the few global platforms and other leading transnational corporations.

Thirdly, the surfing serfs of the world are increasing digitised into slavery to the triad of capitalism, monopoly-capitalism and financialization capitalism where labour is outsmarted by machines.

Capitalism never fade – it just change formations


More MALAYSIAN MANUSCRIPTS


Standard

TOP GLOVE BOTTOM BONDAGE – TYING MODERN SLAVERY IN MONOPOLY-CAPITAL LABOUR ARBITRAGE

PROLOGUE

Not too long ago, during a time of pre-covid19, and in a place not too far away, a country exported 182 billion glove pieces annually that constitute her 65% global market share. The US consumes 150 glove pieces per capita, Italy 123 pieces, Japan 54 pieces, and China a comparatively six pieces from this glove production place.

Quoting Giovanni Arrighi, one may say that ‘the spread of industrialization appears not as a development of the semi-periphery but as peripheralization of industrial activities’ .

1] INTRODUCTION

In a globalised world, the commodity production often resides in Global South whereas the consumption, and the capital financialisation of its production, comes from the Global North.

With the restructuring of monopoly capital on a worldwide scale, which has somewhat given contemporary imperialism a new face and direction (Suwandi, Jonna and Foster, 2019), the way by which global monopolies at the center of a world economy have captured the value generated by labour in the periphery on an unequal exchange basis, monopoly-capitalism is basically getting more labour in exchange for less pay. The inevitable resultant outcome is a change in the global structure of industrial production while maintaining, and often intensifying, the global structure of exploitation and value transfer.

A company like Top Glove where its workers produce 16,000 gloves per capita daily or 200 million natural and synthetic rubber gloves a day when the 44 factory-plants are operating 24 hours a day in three shifts.  It is churning out single-unit gloves destined for community health clinics and medical suites, pharmaceutical chemists and hospitals all over the world, besides the Federal Emergency Management Agency (FEMA). On 18th August 2020, Top Glove Corp Bhd becomes the second most valuable stock on Bursa Malaysia, having displaced Public Bank Bhd. The gap between Top Glove and the local bourse’s No. 1 Malayan Banking Bhd (Maybank) is narrowing. Top Glove captures 26% of the world market share for rubber gloves, and aims to capture 30% of the world market by year-end 2020.

However, at this juncture of an Ecological-Epidemiological-Economic catastrophe in our country, labour advocates had called out that coronavirus has fuelled unfair employment and ‘union-busting’ at factories across Southeast Asia where Global North retailers have cancelled orders or demanded discounts from suppliers in Malaysia, Myanmar, Thailand, Cambodia and the Philippines, leading to many workers going without pay or being sacked. Major brands, including carmaker BMW and fashion label Zara, are investigating reports of mass sackings of union workers in their supply chains.

It is not surprising that many transnational corporations are targeting – and firing – union members while keeping on non-unionised workers, and the continuing outbreak is spurring rollback of rights on issues from decent pay to safe workplaces.

Sunstar Engineering – based near Bangkok – confirmed that the sackings happened but denied singling out unionised workers. The factory has listed Honda, Yamaha, Harley-Davidson, General Motors and Isuzu among its global buyers.

This comes at a time when about 2.5 billion people – more than 60% of the world’s workforce – are informal workers, leaving them particularly at risk of being underpaid, overworked and abused, the International Trade Union Confederation (ITUC) revealed.

No one wanted to leave the union, but it was a matter of survival,” labour unionist Phacharee told the Thomson Reuters Foundation.

2] LAND DEFORESTATION AND LABOUR ARBITRAGE

It has to be said that capitalism since the late 1980s, even as the world is engulfed in an epoch of catastrophe capitalism, is manifesting today in the convergence of (1) the planet’s ecological crisis, (2) the global epidemiological crisis, and (3) the unending world economic crisis. Adding to these unpleasantries of an “empire of chaos,” is the extreme system of imperialist exploitation unleashed by the linkages in the global commodity chains, see Intan Suwandi, Value Chains: The New Economic Imperialism, Monthly Review 2019.

Suwandi shows how multinational corporations use global labour arbitrage to create “global labour value chains” to protect their profit margins, so that supposedly decentralised global production is associated with the growing concentration of profits and economic power.

Another way of putting it is that with the difference in average wages between advanced economies and the rest being very much greater than differences in productivity. This points to higher rates of surplus value being created in the economic ‘periphery’, compared to the imperialist ‘core’. Suwandi’s argument is that it is the structural power of multinationals which enable them to enforce a regime upon production in dependent economies which propel the transfer of very significant quantities of value into their hands, through ‘labour-value commodity chains’ (p.17).

This is where our local corporate capitalists are connecting these nodes of land ecological destruction and labour deprivation. Capital interests – whether private or public in the form of government-link companies (GLCs) – support and fund development, and production-induced changes in land use especially as big estate-plantations like IOI Plantations and Boustead, and the Federal Land Development Authority (FELDA) slashing away pristine forestry to cultivate oil palms or rubber or durians resulting in disease emergence in developing and underdeveloped parts of the world. For instance, there are some transnational-based nations known as the “Soybean Republics” ranging across south America in countries like Bolivia, Paraguay, Argentina, and Brazil where their emergence has the resultant changes in ownership and control of national economies and a new geography of transnational land pooling and real estates’ leasing.

In straddling across national borders, these “commodity countries,” with an organisational flexibly and dexterity in transborder crossing ecologies and political boundaries, are inevitably introducing new epidemiologies accomplished by the circuitry of capital infusion.

Owing to an unequal ecological exchange – by redirecting the worst damage from Big Farms’ industrial agriculture in the Global North to the Global South virgin hinterlands – it has also encouraged developing national government in stripping local resources led by government-link companies (GLCs) latching onto imperial ventures (taking over titleless cultivators land or opening up FELDA frontier-plantations but indebting the settlers or settleless communities in Sabah and Sarawak still unsettled after their timberland has been deforested by commercial loggers). They venture onto new large-scale projects but with scopes ill-defined (a high-speed long-distance railways like the East Coast Rail Line or a Malacca  mega-port or a megacity like Bandar Malaysia). They commodify land usage into a Kulim-like industrial technological park or an oilpalm township into a Cyberjaya multimedia city where kampung or Felda youth are encouraged or even induced to migrate to stay-in to work for a pitiful earning.

Migrated rural youth are bonded into digital infrastructural platforms surviving not unlike their foreparents tapping rubber in estates, but as modern digital slaves.

The plantation system was based on the super-exploitation of labour. Pay was so low that the English assistant Leopold Ainsworth once wondered how the Tamil workers and their families could “possibly exist as ordinary human beings” on the wages paid on his boss’s Malayan plantation. In 1926, the cost of a Papuan indentured laborer was 20 percent of that of a white worker, 25 percent of that of an employed estate manager, and 10 percent of that of a white unskilled laborer.
In fact, the percentage of surplus value gained by Top Glove is exactly similar to labour’s added value but expropriated by such TNCs like Apple, Nike, Swedish retailer Hennes & Mauritz and Spice Girl’s T-shirt under Global North monopoly-capital system.
(see MR Online, 8th. February, 2021).

The central argument is that the surplus value – the added value created by workers in excess of their own labor-cost – is being appropriated by the manufacturing producers and the new share-trading financial capitalists as source of profits, (Marx, The Capital, chapter 8).

3] INDENTURED LABOUR AS ORPHANS OF THE EMPIRE

As Top Glove’s main raw material is latex, we have to tell the story of rubber which is inextricably interwined with the onset of British colonialism, rise of local mercantile-capitalism, and perpetuated with neo-imperialism, and continue in modernity as part and parcel of financialization capitalism in the country.

British colonists introduced rubber to the then Federated States of Malaya in the 1870s, and the plant – originally from the Brazilian Amazon forest – survives in the country’s hot and humid climate marvelously to quickly becoming a major export industry. It gave rise to the emergence of British agency houses (like the Sime Darby, Guthrie, Harrisons and Crosfield financially supported by the Standard Charted and the Hong Kong and Shanghai Bank) to own and control the plantations, besides acting as the intermediaries by sending these rolled rubber sheets to England’s manufacturing plants.

The tale of how one Henry Wickham who stole the Brazilian rubber clones is one of the romantic legends of the British Empire. By his own account, in 1876 Wickham collected over 70,000 hevea seeds from the forests along the Tapajós River. Then, he smuggled the seeds to Joseph Hooker, the eminent botanist who served as director of the Royal Botanic Gardens, London.

With western colonialism in motion, Britain’s ‘forward movement’ in Malaya after the 1870s resulted in the country’s greater integration into the international economy that greatly assisted to facilitate the production of mineral and agricultural commodities. Concurrently, labour migration became a fundamental component of Malaya’s economic growth model, and the associated illed social structures that followed.

Modern days Malaysia’s plantations give glove manufacturers easy access to a crucial raw material: the oozed white sap known as latex or Devil’s Milk – a name given owing to the harsh and misery environment where exploitative tappers worked in the Amazon and Africa (John Tully, The Devils Milk: A Social History of Rubber, NYU Press, Monthly Review Press 2011).

Although so-called natural rubber gloves today make up less than half the market, partly because of some personal allergic skin reactions, Malaysia’s large oil industry, with Petronas at the forefront, provides local glove manufacturers ample supplies of the petrochemicals needed to make synthetic components to produce nitrile rubber, a nitrile-containg polymer used in latex-free laboratory and medical gloves.

Capital, as Marx once wrote, comes into the world “dripping from head to foot, from every pore, with blood and dirt” , and the deep alienation of human beings from their environment in the form of a “metabolic rift” – the ecological disruption in their interrelations with nature as stated by John Bellamy FosterMarx’s Ecology (New York: Monthly Review Press, 2000), ix.

With colonialism in place, the tropical regions saw the expansion of industrial methods of farming that reflected the mass production industries of the British industrial heartlands where men and women spent their lives in Dickensian factories to transform rolls of rubber sheets into pneumatic tyres or similar rubberized end-products. Other large-scale plantations supplied commodities such as coffee, sugar, cotton, and tea – and the rubber latex tapped as rolls of caoutchouc and balls of rubber – known as “niggerheads” from their alleged resemblance to the skulls of black people – arrived in Europe aboard returning slave ships. This was also an era whence the British Empire controlled 33 percent share of the premier slave-trading total in Africa and the Caribbean’s West Indies. The British populace marveled at the rubbery latex for its properties of stretch and bounce, unaware or uncare of the human bondage as the driving force of this abject and horrific imperial practice residence in her own racially conflicted and class-ridden society. In tropical Malaya then, forests were cleared to plant rows after rows of rubber trees seen parading, by the sides of the North-South highway, along present day peninsular Malaysia.

The development of the rubber industry, thus reinforced the connections, and the ensuing contradictions, between Indian labour immobility and capital movement. Indeed, both the Indian and Malayan colonial administrations colluded strategically in planning and organising Indian labour migration to Malaya.

Since rubber cultivation and latex tapping necessitated a large, cheap and “disciplined” workforce that had to be settled and organised to work under pioneering conditions in the country, British India with its teeming poverty-stricken millions and caste-ridden society was the preferred provider for this labour to serve the British colonial capital that properly appropriated the economic surplus that materially and substantially aided their own industrial transition from the eighteenth century onward, (Mohamed Amin and Malcolm Caldwell, Malaya: The Making of a Neo-Colony, Bertrand Russell Peace Foundation, 1977; and Monsoons STORM).

The outlook is particularly gloomy for the then Malaya’s marginalised South Indian plantation workers who became “orphans of empire” that are minutely documented by Amarjit Kaur‘s account of Indian migrant workers in Malaysia part 2, in newmandala and Prakash C. Jain, Exploitation and reproduction of migrant Indian labour in colonial Guyana and Malaysia.

After Amarjit wrote her articles in newmandala, there were poignant letters from family members in south India writing to the Australian academic website seeking, with scarce personal information, forgotten relatives who were shipped to British Malaya and had became orphans of the Empire.

4] LABOUR BONDAGE UNDER MONOPOLY-CAPITAL

Before the advent of modern day slavery, during Western colonialism era, Britain, as stated, controlled 33% of the global of slave-trading; indeed, the Royal African Company, under the reigning arms of the Crown, once held a hefty 90% share of the African slavery in 1690.

The transnational corporations nowadays often than not to openly exercise their ‘collective’ power to pressure national governments to implement business-friendly labour control. During the 1970-2000 Malaysia industrialisation period, TNCs semiconductor firms like Harris, AMD and Motorola were collaborating with Henry Kissinger (then an inward investment advisor to the Indonesian Government) and Jack Welsh of GE and the AFL-CIO in meddling the industrial actions by Malaysian labour by blatantly indulging in union busting (see Bhopal, University of North London).

Also, in response to the increasing number of labour disputes in Korea in 2003, the Seoul Japan Club, an association of Japanese TNCs in Korea, publicly expressed a strong concern that ‘the labour-friendly intervention of Korea’s new government would undermine Korea’s policies to attract foreign investment as well as the image of Korea in the world market’ (Chosun Daily 30 May 2003). 

Indeed, the fact that corporations are free to move to alternative EPZs (an Export Processing Zone is a customs-clearing site where the importation of plant, machinery, equipment and material for the manufacture of export goods under security, without payment of duty, is allowed), the greatest fear to labour movement organisation is foreign-invested firms. It is increasingly clear that TNCs shall solicit government intervention on behalf of firms whenever there are workers’ struggles. The intense competition between countries to attract, and host, more capital by offering favourable conditions greatly boosts the mobility of capital than labour employment, pursuant to reports:
Militant Unionism Kicks out Foreign Investment and Drives National Economy into Collapse (Chunganag Daily, 25 and 26 August, Chosun Daily 26 August, Donga Daily 26 August).

In fact, Nestlé Korea has recorded an average US$1.8 billion net annual profit since 1997, from a US$1.47 billion capital investment. Instead of rewarding the workers whose weekly working hours reached over 50 hours per week, management outsourced its sales department in 2003 and threatened to dismiss its sales workers.
In response to the union’s strike against company restructuring, the chairman of Nestlé Korea said, “It is general practice of MNCs that they relocate the production lines to the neighbouring countries offering favourable business conditions. If we understand these characteristics and behaviour of MNC’s operation practices, it is absolutely an illusion to believe permanent [sic] production facilities in Korea when the current situation continues and repeats. As Korean manager [sic], it is very regrettable that trade union leaders underestimate this problem.” (KCTU 2003).

The fact that Nesclè Korea can recoup its investment within a year in not unrealistic because in many developing countries in the 1970s were enticing monopoly-capital where, for example in Malaysia, there is even a capital allowance scheme for building and plant expenditures incurred, and when incorporated with the accelerated depreciation allowance incentive, companies will virtually have 90% of eligible capital expenditure completely written off within 5 years.

Sri Lanka, a country across the South China Sea on the Indian Ocean, highly reliant on the same products for export as South Korea, faces a similar situation. This leads monopoly-capital to desperately attempt to secure a stable basis for exploitation. Typically, it has become a competition among corporation rivals to attract more investment so the country has become a ‘race-to-the-bottom’ of the worst labour conditions among this category of labour-depressed,  and oppressed, countries. 

In another country-case study, to make garment-producing firms to remain by reinvesting their earnings to finance further industrialisation is by attracting more new investment. This has been one great concern for the Cambodian government, which has no other sources of foreign currency.

In the competition for labour, Shiv Dave, founder of Televisory, a Singapore-based consultancy said that the Malaysia’s rubber glove industry reliant on migrant labour from countries such as Indonesia, Nepal, Bangladesh, and Myanmar would be testing industry players’ abilities. Since 2019, the country’s manufacturing sector has been experiencing acute labour shortages after the government imposed stricter labour requirements and cracked down on foreign workers without work permits.

With migrant workers under repressive colonial-enacted labour legislations that have not changed except with additional legal preferences to the corporate owners and transnational corporations, the precarious labour conditions in Malaysia persist.

This glove industry’s raise to global dominance has created a huge need for foreign workers, leading to controversy over their treatment. The US government had once barred imports of the products from two Top Glove units due to “reasonable evidence of forced labour.

Guardian investigation reported that two giants in rubber glove production, Top Glove and WRP, were allegedly subjecting migrant workers from Nepal and Bangladesh to excessive overtime of up to 160 hours a week, “unsafe” factory conditions, confiscated passports, high recruitment fees that kept them in debt bondage and, in the case of WRP, salaries withheld for months.

For instance, workers from Bangladesh alleged that they had paid recruitment fees of up to 20,000 Malaysian ringgit (£3,700) and workers from Nepal said they had paid up to RM$7,000  (£1,300) to agents in their home countries to come to work for Top Glove in Malaysia. In a statement, Top Glove denied imposing recruitment fees higher than 20% of the workers’ salary, and said it complied with local laws. However, it was even alleged that their salaries were withheld for up to three months at a time. 

The Thomson Reuters Foundation reported, in December 2018, that workers in Top Glove have worked excessive overtime and in some cases exceed the legal limit to help clear debts to recruitment agents.

The exposè prompted investigations by the British government after it found some Top Glove supplies had been used in its hospitals, and by Australian rubber giant Ansell, (theedgemarkets February 01, 2019).

Both Top Glove and WRP were found to be producing medical gloves for brands sold by NHS Supply Chain, the organisation which supplies about 40% of the British National Health Service (NHS) products. NHS Supply Chain has confirmed to the Guardian that it is investigating the allegations. The company has a code of conduct to prevent any forced labour or modern slavery conditions in its supply chain.

In a statement, the Department of Health said: “In line with the government’s policy and leadership on modern slavery, we take any allegations of this kind incredibly seriously and are working with NHS Supply Chain to ensure that these issues are investigated as a matter of urgency.

5] MONOPOLY-CAPITAL ENTANGLEMENT WITH LABOUR

Monopoly-capitalism follows capitalism. Monopoly capitalism is the stage of capitalism which dates from approximately the last quarter of the nineteenth century and reaches full maturity in the period after the Second World War.

It is the concentration and centralization of capital:

(1) Monopolistic organization gives capital an advantage in its struggle with labour, hence tends to raise the rate of surplus value and to make possible a higher rate of accumulation.

(2) With monopoly (or oligopoly – where a state of limited competition, in which a market is shared by a small number of producers or sellers) prices replacing competitive prices, a uniform rate of profit gives way to a hierarchy of profit rate – highest in the most concentrated industries, lowest in the most competitive. This means that the distribution of surplus value is skewed in favour of the larger units of capital which characteristically accumulate a greater proportion of their profits than smaller units of capital, once again making possible a higher rate of accumulation.

(3) On the demand side of the equation, monopolistic industries – typically a market structure characterized by a single seller, selling a unique product in the market – adopt a policy of slowing down and carefully regulating the expansion of productive capacity in order to maintain their higher rates of profit.

The consequences of monopoly mean that the savings potential of the system is increased, while the opportunities for profitable investment are reduced. Other things being equal, therefore the level of income and employment under monopoly capitalism is lower than it would be in a more competitive environment.
Monopoly-capital in seeking cheap agricultural pastures and arbitrage of labour costs is redefining and reimaging the global commodity supply chain in the distribution of its final product. The twenty-first century monopoly-capitalism is scooping returns accruing from land and investment on real estates, from natural resources and long-term commodity contracts. This core feature of economic imperialism cascading through an intensed transformative quality of organization and dominance of monopoly capital, the rampage of peripheral countries’ natural resources is paramount and intense.

By 2010, 79 percent of the world’s industrial workers lived in the Global South, compared to 34 percent in 1950 and 53 percent in 1980, (Smith, Imperialism in the Twenty-First Century, p.101).

The consequences of monopoly-capitalism entanglement with labour is that the exploitation of surplus value of labour wages is most intense. Labour could also be deprived of adequate working conditions or accommodation.  In late 2020, the teratai cluster of Covid19 infections found among Top Grove workers living in the company’s unhealthy staff dormitories in Meru, Kelang is a testimony to willingness of corporate capital producing for monopoly-capitalism in the Global North yet ignoring basic workers’ rights in proper shelter provision in furtherance of exploitation for higher profit.

The Health director-general Tan Sri Dr Noor Hisham Abdullah – affectionately known as the Dr. Fucci of Malaysia – warned of the risk of community infection related to the second generation of infections in the teratai cluster as many more positive cases were detected outside the Enhanced Movement Control Order (EMCO) area.

Whereas the country is caring for the well health being of distant wealthy countries, her healthcare provision is that of inadequate services. It is a nation where the government wears three hats: as a public healthcare service-provider, a controller over privatised hospitals and itself investing in operating private medical hospitals and pharmaceutical companies.

When the members of the National Union of Workers in Hospital Support and Allied Services, or NUWHSAS, were arrested while protesting outside the public hospital in Ipoh, Perak, these members are contracted by the UEMS Edgenta Berhad healthcare support company, which manages the hospital; UEMS is an offspring of rentier capitalism in the country infused with oligarchs’ cronies that are engendered by clientelism (Weiss 2020) which has embedded in, and integral to, political offices where dominant intermediaries become the providers and funders of capital, other than the state itself, and through local level ties with highly personal connections have partisan linkages to capital financialization, (newmandala, October 2020).

UEMS Edgenta had embarked on purported union-busting tactics such as denying proper PPE equipment for union members. Union members also claimed that they were allegedly denied the monthly special government allowance worth RM600 (US$140) meant for frontline workers, and were instead given a one-off cash token worth RM300.

Back in Myanmar, Myan Mode – the Yangon factory that supplies to Mango and Zara retailers – agreed in principle to rehire hundreds of other fired union members when business picks up as and when the pandemic eases.

According to the Solidarity Centre, “It’s a mild victory but it’s remarkable how hard the brands fought against what is a very clear case of union busting,” said Andrew Tillet-Saks, the labour campaigner based in Myanmar. “It’s clear that the brands hold leverage,” he added. “The fact that they don’t step in immediately shows that their commitments to sustainability in the supply chain are nonsense.

We acknowledge an increased risk of union-busting during Covid-19 … (and) have therefore increased our due diligence,” said Morten Norlyk, a spokesman for the Danish retailer Bestseller in Myanmar.

Meanwhile, in the Philippines, the Covid19 pandemics is paving way for labour malpractices where some struggling companies are using Covid-19 fallout as an excuse not to give laid-off employees their entitlements.

It was reported by the Union of Catholic News that a worker came to the Union seeking for legal advice. After working for 27 years in her company, the worker could not work anymore because the company is closing 13 outlets in Manila and filing for bankruptcy. The company had asked her to sign a “voluntary resignation” letter to receive her salary for the whole year.

The Labour Code of the Philippines provides that an employer may terminate an employee for just causes.

Just cause includes serious misconduct or willful disobedience; gross and habitual neglect by an employee; fraud or willful breach of trust; criminal activity or other similar activities.

The Philippines Supreme Court once ruled that “resignation is the voluntary act of an employee who is in a situation where one believes that personal reasons cannot be sacrificed in favor of the exigency of the service, and one has no other choice but to dissociate oneself from employment.

In short, the unnamed worker’s “voluntary resignation” absolved the company from paying her severance which must be computed based on her number of years in the company. This worker merely received the salary for the entire year but not a single centavo to compensate her for 27 years in the company.

Whereas in Thailand, in order to control the spread of the COVID-19 pandemic, the Thai junta government announced an emergency decree which applies to all areas in Thailand from 26 March to 30 April 2020 (“Emergency Decree”) that on 28 April 2020 was extended until 31 May 2020 (“Emergency Decree Period”). Under the Emergency Decree, in pursuant of which is a notification of the Ministry of Labour’s referral of unsettled labour disputes to the labour relations committee for settlement and prohibition on employers to cause a lockout or employees to cause a strike during the period of the emergency situations in accordance with the laws on public administration in emergency situations.

“Clearly some employers believe they can take advantage of the Covid-19 pandemic and economic slowdown to violate workers and their rights with impunity,” said Robert Pajkovski, Thailand programme director at the Solidarity Centre, a US-based charity; see The Thai Labour Movement: Strength Through Unity.

Returning on the final journey home to Malaysia, the Human Resources Ministry had made amendments to the Labour Law, too, justifying that they were in line with the spirit of the International Labour Organisation’s (ILO) Convention 87 on Freedom of Association and Protection of the Right to Organise 1948, allowing a multiplicity of trade unions in an organisation.

However, with the new amendments, these unions, despite obtaining prior recognition, will need to go through another secret ballot to compete with rival unions for sole bargaining rights.

This will definitely create instability and split the union movement, not strengthen it. In fact,
employers and Human Resources Ministry can then promote their preferred unions.
Once a union has been voted in for sole bargaining rights, the remaining unions become defunct as they do not have the bargaining rights.

As such, the only logical reason behind the Human Resources Ministry push to create a multiplicity of unions is to create disharmony among unions to stop them from carrying out their roles effectively.

This is a clear case of state-sponsored union-busting and unfortunately the minister who is supposed to protect labour is, in reality, exploiting workers and unions by abusing his power,” so said J. Solomon, secretary-general of the Malaysian Trade Union Congress (MTUC).

Labour movement is becoming more challenging.

EPILOGUE



With bountiful of revenue-generated profits, Top Glove Corp Bhd is evaluating a plan for dual primary listing on the Hong Kong Stock Exchange (HKEx), in consideration of raising more than US$1 billion from the listing exercise.

According to Bloomberg data, earnings estimates would be at RM$8.26 billion for FY21 ending Aug 31, 2021, with Maybank IB Research analyst Lee Yen Ling’s forecast the highest at RM$11.22 billion, indicating an abundance of Top Glove’s operating cash flow that presents a profit extraction arbitrage opportunity for monopoly capital between the bourses in Malaysia and Hong Kong.

Knight Frank consultancy firm has estimated that Malaysia capital accumulation of wealth-creation is the 10th fastest in the world – with the mean income of RM$7,901 in 2019 – the 2020 wealth report projected that the number of Malaysians with more than US$30 million will swell by 35 per cent between 2019 and 2024, compared with 2 per cent between 2018 and 2019. The CEO of Top Glove had become one of the five new billionaires in the country within the year.

A Global South corporate capital in collaboration with monopoly-capitalists in the Global North has joined the league of industrial tycoons in taking the financialization capitalism route towards capital accumulation by being a top glover binding labour in arbitrage under monopoly-capitalism bondage.

BIBLIOGRAPHY

Aliran:
https://m.aliran.com/aliran-csi/aliran-csi-2017/history-labour-movement-malaysia/

Jomo K. Sundaram:
https://www.networkideas.org/news-analysis/2021/02/road-to-hell-paved-with-good-intentions/

https://www.thesundaily.my/opinion/caught-in-a-tangled-web-of-vaccine-nationalism-FM6493304

Monsoons STORM:
https://monsoonsstorms.wordpress.com/2021/02/02/covid19-and-the-circuitry-of-capital/

https://monsoonsstorms.wordpress.com/2021/01/06/breaking-the-glass-screen-framing-monopoly-capitalism-in-global-commodity-chains/

Monthly Review:

https://monthlyreviewarchives.org/index.php/mr/article/view/MR-072-03-2020-07_9

Rob Wallace, Alex Liebman, Luis Fernando Chaves and Rodrick Wallace in Monthly Review, 1st. May, 2020; and Rob Wallace Big Farms Make Big Flu:Dispatches on Infectious Disease, Agribusiness, and the Nature of Science: https://monthlyreview.org/product/big_farms_make_big_flu/

Newmandala:
https://www.newmandala.org/aliens-in-the-land-indian-migrant-workers-in-malaysia-part-2/

Standard

BIG FARMS SMALL FARMERS – CAPITALISM AND UNSETTLED LANDLESSNESS

1. INTRODUCTION

We have so much land in Malaysia with a small population of +30 million compared with our ASEAN neighbours, and yet we have to import over RM$50 billion in food commodities annually to feed the nation.

Land in Malaysia that could be used to grow food is planted with palm oil to ‘feed’ the Global North need from cosmetics and as cooking oil to lubricants or as a biofuel, whilst the devils milk latex is oozed out of rubber trees to make tyres and gloves for cosmopolitan western countries. The farmers in the highly productive Bertam Valley in the Cameron Highlands prefer to grow chrysanthemums for the Japanese market as they are a more valuable crop than vegetables for local consumption.

These are typical failure features of carnivorous capitalism in big agrobusiness.

Malaysia’s agricultural sector is strongly biased towards large-scale agriculture. The estate (plantation) sector is predominantly a producer of oil palm and rubber accounting for 40% of the country’s agricultural area. These estates are big – each individual unit commonly covering 2,000-10,000 hectares. They are often organised in units managed by global companies such as Sime Darby; this company alone controls 300,000 hectares in Malaysia.

The land development schemes, started by the Federal Land Development Authority (FELDA), is managed like a feudal land-owner than as a co-operative occupying 21% of the land.

Over 60% of land area is devoted to two main crops neither of which provides anything in the way of food for the Malaysian population. 

The remaining 40% is managed by family households on independent smallholdings of less than 2 hectares in size, and not all of these lands are used for farming (only 7.8 million hectares, according to the Food and Agriculture Organisation (FAO).

2. ESTATE CAPITALISM

Though agriculture makes up 7-8% GDP and employs only 4% of the workforce, the surplus value of processed oilpalms and rubber is not accounted. In 2017, export earnings from rubber and rubber products contributed RM$32.1 billion to national exports; total oil palm export was valued at RM$71. 5 billion.

With the British ‘forward movement’ of colonialism in place, the adoption of industrial farming transformed rolls of rubber sheets into pneumatic tyres or similar rubberized end-products in Dickensian-like factories in the United Kingdom.

The indentured and kangani-recruited but marginalised South Indian plantation workers eventually became those “orphans of empire”. 

By late twentieth century, industrial capitalism has not changed, but evolved into globalized capitalism that increasingly adopted the form of interlinked commodity chains controlled by transnational corporations, connecting diversified production zones, primarily in the Global South, with the high point of world consumption, finance, and accumulation mainly in the Global North. These commodity chains constitute primarily the circuits of capital globally that is identified as late imperialism with the rise of generalized monopoly-finance capital, see John Bellamy Foster, “Late Imperialism,” Monthly Review 71, no. 3 (July–August 2019): 1–19; Samir AminModern Imperialism, Monopoly Finance.

Under this system, exorbitant imperial rents from the control of global production are obtained not only from the global labor arbitrage, through which transnational corporations with their headquarters in the Global North overexploit industrial labour in the periphery, but also increasingly through the global land arbitrage, in which agribusiness multinationals expropriate cheap land (and labour) in the Global South so as to produce export crops mainly for sale in the Global North, see Intan SuwandiValue Chains (New York: Monthly Review Press, 2019), 32–33, 53–54.

The IMF, under its Structural Adjustment Programme, or the World Bank often imposed upon African debtor countries to develop their exports of cash crops at the expense of imports and expenditure on social welfare, resulting in cutting subsidies into local food production.

On some other examples: trade terms in Jamaica mean that local food industries go out of business because of the dumping of cheap, subsidised food from the USA. Food aid is sent to Ethiopia, which could do a better job of feeding itself if the coffee price was not driven down by commodity markets in London or New York. In Mugabe’s Zimbabwe, food aid does not reach all needy inhabitants because of their political affiliations. Hershey purchased so many cocoa beans in the futures market that prices rose by more than 30 percent; the Ghana Cocoa Board accused the firm on the abuse of the derivatives market to impoverish the West African farmer.

It seems that world systems mean that nations are not allowed to feed their citizens.

Agribusinesses,” Rob Wallace writes, “are moving their companies into the Global South to take advantage of cheap labor and cheap land,” and “spreading their entire production line across the world.” Avians, hogs, and humans all interact to produce new diseases. “Influenzas,” Wallace tells us, “now emerge by way of a globalized network of corporate feedlot production and trade, wherever specific strains first evolve. With flocks and herds whisked from region to region – transforming spatial distance into just-in-time expediency – multiple strains of influenza are continually introduced into localities filled with populations of susceptible animals.” Wallace, Big Farms Make Big Flu.

With monopoly-capital in place, by the 21st. Century, the Great Financial Crisis of 2007–09 was inevitable. The result is the greatest mass migration in human history, with people being thrown off the land in a global process of depeasantization, altering the agroecology of whole regions, replacing traditional agriculture with monocultures, and pushing populations into urban slums, see Farshad Araghi, “The Great Global Enclosure of Our Times,” in Hungry for Profit, ed. Fred Magdoff, John Bellamy Foster, and Fredrick H. Buttel (New York: Monthly Review Press, 2000), 145–60.

Today’s global commodity chains – or what we call labor-value chains – are organized primarily in order to exploit lower unit labor costs (taking into account both wage costs and productivity) in the poorer countries of the Global South where world industrial production is now predominantly located. Unit labor costs in India in 2014 were 37 percent of the U.S. level, while China’s and Mexico’s were 46 and 43 percent, respectively. Indonesia was higher with unit labor costs at 62 percent of the U.S. level, see Suwandi, Value Chains, 59–61; John  Smith, Imperialism in the Twenty-First Century (New York: Monthly Review Press, 2016).

3. UNSETTLED LANDLESSNESS

The country’s peasantry mass constitutes the main stream of the economically active population, provides the stable food of the population in padi cultivation, and owns 61% of the rubber smallholding acreage before independence (see STORMcontinuance of neo-colonialism) with agriculture contributing 12 percent to the then national GDP.

To forestall any peasantry revolt, the Federal Land Development Authority (FELDA) was formed. FELDA has evolved from a land settlement agency to a plantation company with all the negative aspects of capitalism excess within a settlement colonialism environment, (see Keith Sutton and Amriah Buang, Geography, Vol. 80, No. 2, April 1995) where lowly-paid foreign labour is exploited to harvest yields rather than done by the settler-owners or their children themselves; and where monopoly-capital siphoned off the surplus value of migrant labour and the wealth of settlers through financialization capitalism by way of credit payments on food items and loans repayments on household equipment and leased vehicles.

In furtherance with corporisation, FELDA has became Felda Global Venture FGV but went down as a loosing entity to be resurrected by one government after the next (from PH 2018 to PN 2020) without much success in settling majority of those who are landless nor those with unsettled debts; many displaced interior communities in Sabah and Sarawak are still without land titles as the development of underdevelopment undermined these states.

Where development means clearing of canopies of forested land. This deforestation quickly exhausts the soil in the interest of maximizing profits. Marx had warned that the development of productive forces and technology under capitalist relations of production does not adequately prepare the conditions for human emancipation, but on the contrary, causes a deep alienation of human beings from their environment in the form of a “metabolic rift” – the ecological disruption in their interrelations with nature, see John Bellamy Foster, Marx’s Ecology (New York: Monthly Review Press, 2000), ix.

With onslaught of capital-intensive industrial Agribusinesses, food production was neglected to country’s peril.

4. FOOD INSUFFICIENCY AND FOOD INSECURITIES

According to the Minister of Agriculture and Agro-Based Industry, Salahuddin Ayub, in the event of a global food crisis, Malaysia can only last for two days, compared to China and our neighbour Thailand, which can survive with local produce for six to eight months.

Malaysia’s total padi cropping area is about 0.70 million hectares, which is the lowest in Southeast Asia. The top three rice producers in the regionn – namely Indonesia, Vietnam and Thailand – have allocated 11.50, 7.54 and 10.83 million hectares, respectively (United States Department of Agriculture [USDA], 2020). In 2018, the production volume of rice in Malaysia totaled approximately 1.7 million metric tons.

If all of Malaysia were turned over to rice farming then the calories they could produce every day would be total square km multiplied by calories per sq km, or 322,665 x 2004 = 646,620,000 calories. Rounding down, this is 646.6 million calories, but it is still barely serve 1% of their daily needs.

Various food security programmes were developed after the nation’s independence in 1957, whereby multiple strategic interventions have taken place through the setting up of diverse government institutions and policy initiatives (Fahmi etal., 2013). These programmes, among others, include paddy stockpiles, price control, guaranteed minimum price (GMP) and stipulating production-driven targets, known as SSL.

However, future development of the rice sector in Malaysia is prophesied to face multiple challenges, including complex shifts in climatic conditions and impacts of climate change, scarce arable farmland, social and economic transformations, the influx of low-priced rice from neighbouring countries, insufficient property assets and dependency on smallholder agriculture, see R. B. Radin Firdaus, Mou Leong Tan, Siti Rahyla Rahmat & Mahinda Senevi Gunaratne, Paddy rice and food security in Malaysia: A review of climate change impacts, 14 September 2020.

The Malaysian government had aimed to become self-sufficient in the staple food of rice and had tried to help the independent smallholder sector for the past 30 years. Financial assistance and technical help have been provided but in 2012 the sector still provided less than three quarters of the country’s rice needs. In 2019, rice imports quantity for Malaysia was around 1,100 thousand tonnes; food security in Malaysia has not been supported empirically, though.


Meanwhile, many small and impoverished farmers, however, are hooked and locked into an unproductive agricultural system that causes and encourages them to look elsewhere, and particularly towards the urban areas, to seek higher income jobs.

Malthus saw the resource (food production green line) increasing arithmetically whilst population (red line) increased geometrically. Boserup agreed that agricultural innovations and improvements would lead to a significant increase in production; research completed by Tiffin et al. (1994) in Machakos, Kenya had shown Boserup’s vision was correct.

5. CAPITALISM AND CONSUMPTION INEQUITIES

Although modern human societies have attained  an unprecedented levels of wealth, there is a significant amount of the world’s population continues to suffer from hunger or food insecurity on a daily basis. In Agriculture and Food in Crisis, Fred Magdoff and Brian Tokar said that nowhere more evident than in the production and distribution of food.

One needs to know that the Big Farm production is shaped by a system that is geared towards capital creation and generarion of profit above all else, with food as nothing but an afterthought.

It is technically possible to feed to world’s people, but it is not possible to do so as long as capitalism exists. We need to create a human-centered and ecologically sound system of food production, from viability to sustainable livelihoods.

For instance, soy has become one of the world’s most important agroindustrial commodities – serving as the nexus for the production of food, animal feed, fuel and hundreds of industrial products – and South America has become its leading production region. However, the soy boom on this continent entangles transnational capital and commodity flows and disrupted social relations deeply in contested ecologies and economies, see The Journal of Peasant Studies : Soy Production in South America: Globalization and New Agroindustrial Landscapes.      
and John Wilkinson, The Globalization of Agribusiness and Developing World Food Systems, Monthly Review, Sep 01, 2009.

The outcome is that, for instance, prominent transnationals have had an important presence in the Brazilian agrifood industry since its birth; players include: Nestlé, Unilever, Anderson Clayton, Corn Products Company, Dreyfus, and the Argentine transnational Bunge y Borne (now simply Bunge). They were later followed, as different markets matured, by Kraft, Nabisco, General Foods, and Cargill from the United States, and United Biscuits, Bongrain, Danone, Parmalat, and Carrefour from Europe.

The consequences are that uneven and often uncoordinated foray of metropolitan corporate capital is subjugating the agriculture and domestic food markets of many developing countries, particularly smaller, peripheral ones undergoing rapid urbanization, to the needs of global agribusiness monopoly-capital.

Therefore, as an independent nation, we need to redefine agriculture – and organic farming – on a large scale to push for radical land reform and national food sovereignty. This is where the concentrated monopoly capitalism role in defining and controlling the supply chain from soil to souls will no doubt has to come to be increasingly understood and realized as food politics for the rakyat.

6. LAND FOR THE MILLENNIALS

Any future generation’s government should gazette Felcra lands and other idle lands into “permanent food production” lands instead of rehabilitating them into rubber or oil palm plantations, especially for corporate capital.

Any “landless farmer”, renting land to carry out cultivation is a long-term commitment for  whom one is passionate about growing things and a love to the land being farmed.

Neither should any official expects these millennials to squat on TOL (Temporary Occupation of Land) land, which requires a yearly renewal of their land licences because twenty years down the road, they may have to vacate their farms if the authorities refuse to renew their TOL licences and they may face evictions as are those cases in Cameron Highlands and Pahang durian farmers.

It rests upon the concept of Sovereignty whereby argumentatively, a wholesome Land Reform is necessary for the country because unlike what had been formulated and executed in South Korea and Taiwain, we have not –  and just like the national debt and economic growth stagnation persistent in our national economic – we never accept and endure structural politico-economic changes throughout the three financial crises experienced (AFC1997, dotcom2001 and GFC2007) and a present and imminent pandemic that is accentuated as never before the interlinked ecological, epidemiological, and economic vulnerabilities imposed by capitalism.

Alternatively, a mid-term tactical implementation is to have an extensive land rehabilitation projects for small farms’ agricultural produce that could possibly be seriously considered, too.

However, it should not – never ever – be joint ventures in the guise of a triple alliance between the federal government (Agriculture and Food Industries Ministry), state development corporations or GLCs and the private sector corporate capital because it is capitalism at its best to exploit, and eventually exporiate the sacred surplus value of labour.

All unsettled LANDLESSNESS RAKYAT2 should be part of a collaborative-engaged cooperative movement for a better and an equitable wealth-sharing struggle towards a socialist state.

Standard

Monopoly Capital: Debt and Stagnation under Financialization Capitalism

Adapted the theoretical framework, and material contents therein, from John Bellamy Foster, New Imperialism of Globalized Monopoly Finance Capital, MonthlyReview, 2015, and adopted the arguments, with added new materials, diagrams and footnotes, from the blog in Post-1997 Political Economy.
____________________
PROLOGUE

Former deputy governor of Bank Negara Malaysia,
Dr Sukudhew (Sukhdave) Singh, wrote an article in LinkedIn and reposted in TheEdge exerting that: Malaysia risks not being a high-income economy even over the next 20 years, that is commented in Post-1997 Political Economy, followed by Towards Post-2020 Political Economy and Financialization of Healthcare: Capital and Health Equities, besides exploratory studies that were completed in Financialization Capitalism: Penetration of Neo-Imperialism in Malaysia and Financialization Capitalism in a Covid19 Political Economy – underlying the emergence, and intrusiveness, of financialization capitalism as a contributing cause to the widening national debt and the consequential economic stagnation in Malaysia political economy.


1. INTRODUCTION

That what is widely referred to as neoliberal globalization in the twenty-first century is in fact a historical product of the shift to global monopoly-finance capital or what Samir Amin calls the imperialism of “generalized-monopoly capitalism.”

In the twenty-first century imperialism is thus taking on a new, more developed phase related to the globalization of production and finance.

The shift of manufacturing industry in recent decades from the Global North to the Global South. In 1980 the share of world industrial employment of developing countries had risen to 52 percent; by 2012 this had increased to 83 percent. 

By 2013, 61 percent of the total worldwide inward flow of foreign direct investment was in developing and transitional economies, up from 33 percent in 2006 and 51 percent in 2010.

From 1970 to 1989 the average annual per capita GDP of the developing countries, excluding Greater China, was a mere 6.0 percent of the per capita GDP of the G7 countries (the United States, Japan, Germany, France, the United Kingdom, Italy, and Canada). For the period of 1990 to 2013, this had dropped to only 5.6 percent.

Meanwhile, for the forty-eight Least Developed Countries, average annual per capita GDP as a share of that of the G7 declined over the same periods from 1.5 percent to a mere 1.1 percent.

The Economist announced that this trend has now reasserted itself. At the present rate of growth in the developing world, The Economist insisted, it would take developing/emerging countries as a group (outside of China) more than a century -and even possibly as long as three centuries – to catch up with the income levels of the rich countries of the center, (The Economist, “The Headwinds Return,” September 13, 2014).

2. THE SCENARIOS

Behind such dirt wages in the periphery lies the whole history of imperialism and the fact that in 2011 the global reserve army of labor (adding up the unemployed, vulnerably employed, and economically inactive population) numbered some 2.4 billion people, compared to a global active labor army of only 1.4 billion. It is this global reserve army – predominantly in the Global South, but also growing in the Global North – which holds down the labor income in both center and periphery, keeping wages in the periphery well below the average value of labor power worldwide, as articulated by John Bellamy Foster, Robert W. McChesney and R. Jamil Jonna in The Global Reserve Army of Labor and the New Imperialism.


Consequently, big winners are the transnational corporations. Apple subcontracts the production of the component parts of its iPhones in a number of countries with the final assembly in China subcontracted to Foxconn. Owing to low-end wages paid for labor-intensive assembly operations, Apple’s profits on its iPhone 4 in 2010 were found to be 59 percent of the final sales price. 

For each iPhone 4 imported from China to the United States in 2010, retailing at $549, about $10 went to labor costs for production of components and assembly in China, amounting to 1.8 percent of the final sales price, and Jason Dedrick, “Capturing Value in Global Networks: Apple’s iPad and iPhone,” Paul Merage School of Business, University of California, Irvine, July 2011, see Figure 1 below:

Another model, another configuration with labour cost 1.6% of final sales price; China’s labour cost one-quarter of total labour

In the international garment industry, in which production takes place almost exclusively in the Global South, direct labor cost per garment is typically around 1–3 percent of the final retail price, according to senior World Bank economist Zahid Hussain. Wage costs for an embroidered logo sweatshirt produced in the Dominican Republic run at around 1.3 percent of the final retail price in the United States, while the labor cost (including the wages of floor supervisors) of a knit shirt produced in the Philippines is 1.6 percent. Labor costs in countries such as China, India, Indonesia, Vietnam, Cambodia, and Bangladesh were considerably lower than in the above cases, see Zahid Hussain, “Financing Living Wage in Bangladesh’s Garment Industry,” End Poverty in South Asia, South Asian Region of the World Bank, August 3, 2010, http://blogs.worldbank.org.

The surplus value captured from such workers is thus enormous, while being disguised by the fact that the lion’s share of so-called “value added” is attributed to activities (marketing, distribution, corporate salaries) in the wealthy importing country, removed from direct production costs, see Figure 2 below on a respective example by an industrial sector in oil production upon which surplus value is extracted from labour. In 2010, the Swedish retailer Hennes & Mauritz was purchasing T-shirts from subcontractors in Bangladesh, paying the workers on the order of 2–5 cents (euro) per shirt produced.

HIGH PROFIT margin goes to R&D, including design ( or geo-surveying in oil production ), Global North salaries & bonuses and MARKETING (or retail distribution in oil industry). The “extracted surplus value” is represented by the “smile curve.” The inverted sad smile is represented by workers-in-assembly

Nike, a pioneer in Non-Equity Modes of International Production, outsources all of its production to subcontractors in countries such as South Korea, China, Indonesia, Thailand, and Vietnam. In 1996, a single Nike shoe consisting of fifty-two components was manufactured by subcontractors in five different countries. The entire direct labor cost for the production of a pair of Nike basketball shoes retailing for $149.50 in the United States in the late 1990s was 1 percent, or $1.50.

A part of the imperialist rent remains in the peripheral country and is not transferred to the center, but constitutes rather a payment to local ruling classes for their roles in the globalization game. About $21 trillion of this global tribute, meanwhile, is currently parked abroad in tax-haven islands, “the fortified refuge of Big Finance.” see International Consortium of Investigative Journalists on their Fin-Tech files, and the Guardian,  “£13tn Hoard Hidden from Taxman by Global Elite” July 21, 2012, and Nicholas Shaxson, Treasure Islands (London: Palgrave Macmillan, 2011), 7.

3. FINANCIAL CAPITALISATION

Under these circumstances, as corporations in the 1970s and ’80s sought to hold onto and expand their growing economic surplus in the face of diminishing investment opportunities, they poured their massive surpluses into the financial structure, seeking and obtaining rapid returns from the securitization of all conceivably ascertainable future income streams. Increased concentration (“mergers and acquisitions”) and its attendant new debt, securitizations representing the income stream of already-existing mortgages and consumer debt that piled new debt on old, and new issues of debt and equity that capitalized the potential future monopoly income of patent, copyright, and other intellectual property rights, all followed one another. The financial sector provided every sort of financial instrument that could arguably be serviced by a putative income stream, including from the trading in financial instruments themselves. The result, as Magdoff and Sweezy already documented in the early stages of the process from the late 1970s to the ’90s, was a vast increase in the financial superstructure of the capitalist economy.

This financialization of the economy had three major effects.

First, it served to further uncouple in space and time – though a complete uncoupling is impossible – the amassing of financial claims of wealth or “asset accumulation” from actual investment, i.e., capital accumulation. This meant that the leading capitalist economies became characterized by a long-term amassing of financial wealth that exceeded the growth of the underlying economy (a phenomenon recently emphasized in a neoclassical vein by Thomas Piketty) – creating a more destabilized capitalist order in the center, manifested in the dramatic rise of debt as a share of GDP.

Secondly, the financialization process became the major basis (together with the revolution in communications and digitalized technology) for a deepening and broadening of commodification throughout the globe, with the center economies no longer constituting to the same extent as before the global centers of industrial production and capital accumulation, but rather relying more and more on their role as the centers of financial control and asset accumulation. This was dependent on the capture of streams of commodity income throughout the world economy, including the increased commodification of other sectors – primarily services that were only partially commodified previously, such as communications, education, and health services, see STORM: Financialization of Healthcare: Capital and Health Equities.

The third point, it is relevant to read: Paul A. Baran and Paul M. SweezyMonopoly Capital (New York: Monthly Review Press, 1966), 107–8; Paul M. Sweezy, “Obstacles to Economic Development,” in C.H. Feinstein, Socialism, Capitalism, and Economic Growth (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1967), 194–95, to get the underlying rationality, and that is, “the financialization of the capital accumulation process,” as Sweezy called it, led to an enormous increase in the fragility of the entire capitalist world economy, which became dependent on the growth of the financial superstructure relative to its productive base, with the result that the system was increasingly prone to asset bubbles that periodically burst, threatening the stability of global capitalism as a whole – most recently in the Great Financial Crisis of 2007–2009.

4. MONOPOLY CAPITAL

Given its financial ascendancy, the United States is uniquely able to externalize its economic crises on other economies, particularly those of the global South. As Yanis Varoufakis notes in The Global Minotaur, “To this day, whenever a crisis looms, capital flees to the greenback. This is exactly why the Crash of 2008 led to a mass inflow of foreign capital to the dollar, even though the crisis had begun on Wall Street.”; see Yanis Varoufakis, The Global Minotaur (London: Zed, 2011), 100–102;

The phase of global monopoly-finance capital, tied to the globalization of production and the systematization of imperial rent, has generated a financial oligarchy and a return to dynastic wealth, mostly in the core nations, confronting an increasingly generalized (but also highly segmented) working class worldwide. On the growing role of dynastic wealth see Thomas Piketty, Capital in the Twenty-First Century  (Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press, 2014), 439–43.

The leading section of the capitalist class in the core countries now consists of what could be called global rentiers, dependent on the growth of global monopoly-finance capital, and its increasing concentration and centralization, Fred Magdoff and John Bellamy Foster, “Stagnation and Financialization,” Monthly Review 66, no. 1 (May 2014): 1–23.

The reproduction of this new imperialist system, as Amin explains in Capitalism in the Age of Globalization, rests on the perpetuation of five monopolies: (1) technological monopoly; (2) financial control of worldwide markets; (3) monopolistic access to the planet’s natural resources; (4) media and communication monopolies; and (5) monopolies over weapons of mass destruction.

Behind all of this lie the giant monopolistic firms themselves, with the revenue of the top 500 global private firms currently equal to about 30 percent of world revenue, funneled primarily through the centers of the capitalist system and the core financial markets.

As Boron points out with respect to the world’s 200 largest multinational corporations, “96 percent…have their headquarters in only eight countries, are legally registered as incorporated companies of eight countries; and their boards of directors sit in eight countries of metropolitan capital. Less than 2 percent of their boards of directors’ members are non-nationals…. Their reach is global, but their property and their owners have a clear national base.”

5. DEBT AND STAGNATION

The total debt service (% of GNI) in Malaysia was reported at 3.6036 % in 2016, according to the World Bank collection of development indicators, compiled from officially recognized sources like values, historical data, forecasts and projections as on December of 2020.

[Total debt service is the sum of principal repayments and interest actually paid in currency, goods, or services on long-term debt, interest paid on short-term debt, and repayments (repurchases and charges) to the IMF]

AND

From the Bank Negara Malaysia Report on  Indebted to Debt: An Assessment of Debt Levels we noted that individual borrowers are more likely to have  negative financial margin if they :

(i) earn less than RM3,000 per month; and/or
(ii) have a DSR level of above 60%.

[(DSR) Debt Service Ratio = The ratio of total monthly bank and non-bank debt obligations to monthly disposable income (net of statutory deductions]

Besides,
Loans for the purchase of residential properties
remain the largest component of household
debt, representing 52% of total household loans.
The significant contribution of housing loans
towards household debt raises two key issues, namely, housing affordability and the necessity
of owning a home.

However, with a growing mismatch between prices of new house launches and households’ actual affordability, imbalances in the housing market have worsened in recent years.
In fact, in certain parts of Malaysia, the median house price is as high as five times the annual median household income, rendering houses in these areas ‘seriously unaffordable’.

[Affordability thresholds are based on the Median Multiple approach by Demographia International (2017)].

This has led to households needing to borrow more for house purchases with the average size of housing loans approved increasing from RM180,275 to RM420,230 over the past 10 years.

THOUGH,
Debt service charges are expected to remain manageable at RM34.9 billion or 15.4% of total projected government revenue in 2020, despite being higher than the initial estimate of 14.3% announced under Budget 2020.

The increase in debt service charges is due to an anticipated drop in public revenue given the energence of Covid-19 pandemic and the onset of lower crude oil prices, according to the Economic Outlook 2021 as reported by Wong Ee Lin, theedgemarkets.com, November 06, 2020.

However, like preceeding years, the financing cost of domestic debt instruments is expected to contribute the largest share at 97.7% of debt service charges, while the balance is from stable offshore borrowings at RM29.3 billion, mainly in the US dollar (54.6%) and Japanese yen (44.8%).

Further, owing to the Covid-19 pandemic, the investors’ interest in debt papers have shifted to short-tenure instruments. As at end-September 2020, the share of short-term papers with remaining maturity of five years and below had increased to 39% from 37.5% in 2019.

As a consequence of the above stated parameters, the federal government debt had grown to RM874.3 billion or 60.7% of gross domestic product (GDP) as at end-September 2020, of which RM845 billion was domestic debt, compared with RM792.99 billion previously.

With the  DEFICIT likely to increase, the Government expects its fiscal deficit to swell to 6% of Gross Domestic Product (GDP) in 2020  –  the largest gap since the Global Financial Crisis in 2008 (GFC2008), due to the additional stimulus packages to lift the country’s economy out of the doldrum plus lower GDP as a result of the COVID-19 outbreak.

As a result, there is an estimated PUBLIC REVENUE SHORTFALL estimated at around 20% from the budget estimates. In the Fiscal Policy review, the Ministry of Finance said the lower than expected revenue will be cushioned by additional dividends and a special contribution from Government entities such as Petroliam Nasional Bhd (Petronas), Khazanah Nasional Bhd and Retirement Fund (Inc) (KWAP)

Whether the expected high amount of dividends from Petronas as in previous years is questionable, besides Khazanah’s contributions is marginal  compared to Petronas whereas whatever can issued from KWAP would impact possibly on its future dividends payout, likely effecting it’s long term sustainability, too.

Whatever, the bad debt is worrisome.

World Bank Group lead economist Richard Record had indicated that Malaysia has already depleted much of its available fiscal space and would emerge from the current crisis with a larger burden of debt and contingent liabilities despite the debt ratio had been approved by Parliament to increase from 55% to 60% of the gross domestic product (GDP). There would be difficult intertemporal constraints to further expand expenditures on relief and consumption-supporting stimulus over the near term.

This scenario shall leave national economy less endowed to invest in lasting recovery while maintaing growth in the future.

A paper published by the International Monetary Fund titled ‘Debt and Growth: Is There a Magic Threshold?’’ stated that countries with a debt-to-GDP ratio of 90 per cent and above could experience a dramatic decline in economic growth.

Even Moody Services had stated that the still-wide deficit for 2021 would increase the government’s fiscal consolidation challenge over the next few years. Further, any back-loading of efforts to reduce its debt burden over the year 2022 and 2023, will leave our national debt to the next generation of political leaders, and the present youth populace, to burden.

To finance the estimated deficit of between six and seven per cent, the national economy needs an increase in its borrowings beyond the self-imposed debt ceiling of 55 per cent of the GDP that have since upgraded to 60% by Parliament on 24th August 2020.

To a few local economists, in the financial institutions and stockbrokerage, their unsaid projection is that a 75% of GNP in the debt ceiling could only vindicate Sukhdave‘s pessimism on country’s growth rate and the ominous signs in the Post-1997 Political Economy paper.

However, empirical studies have revealed that the accumulation of external debt is typically associated with an increase in Malaysia’s economic growth up to an optimal level only. Any additional increase of external indebtedness beyond that specific level would inversely contributed to a detrimental national economy; as validated by World Bank sentiment as stated above.

This is thus likely scenario since Post-1997 period whence the growth rate had halved of what was Malaysia economic performance since then. There were visible increases in flow of money in the economy as per Post-1997 Political Economy:

Since 1997, the country had relied extensively on these Malaysian Government Securities for budget deficit financing where part of the budget deficits was financed by creating or printing new
currency notes (“helicopters’ monies”). Also part of the debt papers was monetized; therefore, money supply and currency in circulation increased sharply since 1999, to see Figures 4 and 5 in the Mohamed Aslam and Raihan Jaafar paper.

Government issuance of new debit papers: floated upward in the AFC1997, then another sitcom burst splurge 2001, followed by the GFC2018 spike that continued upward thence
helicopters’ monies” circulating in the market since AFC1997

In short, the amount of money floating around is not to generate wealth but within the circuit of financialization capitalism components of FIREs (finance, interests, real estate) are in furtherance of repaying mortgage loans, hire purchases, insurances, real estates tax dues and other debt interests.


Then, there is  the leakage outside the country through the estimated 5 million (2 millions registered and 3 million illegals) migrant workers who remitted their salaries homes; Rosli and Kumar had researched and written that already in 2006  the remittances made in the Malaysian economy amounted to ₤72M monthly (about RM$500 million every month, then).

Not only a large sum of money flows out of the country, migrant workers do not spend much locally to create a spread effect to contribute, and induce, economic growth; typically, a migrant worker would only spend MY$ 200 (₤29) monthly. This amount, if compared to a Malaysian’s monthly expenditure is very low; on average, the Malaysian locals spend MY$1,943 per month in urban areas and MY$1,270 in rural areas,(Department of Statistics Malaysia, 2004/5).

The high percentage of immigrant construction
workers exposes the country to high remittances that disturbs the economic cycle flow in the form of leakages (Mustapa and Pasquire, 2007), thus strangling economic growth.

Mohamed Aslam and Raihan Jaafar had expressed to the effect of budget deficits on macroeconomics in terms of crowding out private investment, increasing interest rates, expanding money supply and escalating consumer price and in certain extent affect exchange rate. Government bonds issued to finance budget deficits are also in question as part of the net wealth of private sectors. This is because if there is a continuous growth of debt, creditors may become concerned about the government’s initiative to repay it. Over time, these creditors will expect higher interest payments to provide a greater return for their increased perceived risk as it is widely acknowledged that higher interest costs dampen economic growth.

EPILOGUE

This financialization of the economy had these major effects:

1] It uncouples spatial temporally the amassing of financial claims of wealth or “asset accumulation” from actual investment, that is, capital accumulation.

This meant that the leading capitalist economies became characterized by a long-term amassing of financial wealth that exceeded the growth of the underlying economy  creating a more destabilized capitalist order in the center, manifested in the dramatic rise of debt as a share of GDP.

2] Then, financialization process becomes the major basis (assisted by digitalized technology) for a deepening and broadening of commodification throughout the globe.

With the Global North economies as the centers of financial control and asset accumulation and capturing streams of commodity income throughout the world economy, including the increased commodification of other sector – primarily services that were only partially commodified (read privatized and commercialised) previously, such as communications, education, and health services.

3] Third, “the financialization of the capital accumulation process,” as Sweezy called it, led to an enormous increase in the fragility of the entire capitalist world economy. We became increasingly prone to asset bubbles threatening the stability of global capitalism as a whole since the Great Financial Crisis of 2007–2009 (GFC-2007) experience that we never able to sustain the high 8% growth rate as before because real structural reforms were not performed in the country.

We are, as a nation, fossilized in a stupor state from emergence of the Srivijaya and Majaphit empires, intrusions by the Portuguese and Dutch, colonised by the British, occupied by the Japanese and under neo-Colonialism and neo-Imperialism since ever under a thorough Kleptocracy governance.


APPENDIX

Nakornthab (2010) indicates that mortgage loan constitutes the largest portion of Malayia’s household debts, follows by hire-purchase loan, credit card loan and personal loan. Yusof, Rokis and Jusoh (2015) claim that Malay and Indian ethnic are vulnerable to financial shocks due to high household debts.

Consequently, the financial situation for many Malaysian households has already reached a vulnerable level (Rani et al.,2017; Yusof et al., 2015). 

Olin Liu, Malaysia: From Crisis to Recovery, IMF Occasional Paper No: 207.

Standard

POLITICAL ECONOMY OF COVID19

THE CORONAVIRUS

PROLOGUE

A 41- year old man from Selangor – on a special Air Asia flight bringing Malaysians and non-citizen family members home from epic centre Wuhan landed in KLIA at 5:57 am Tuesday 4 February 2020 – became the first Malaysiam tested positive for Covid19.

INTRODUCTION

After a local largest cluster linked to a Tablighi Jamaat religious gathering held in Sri Petaling, Kuala Lumpur in late February and early March, leading to massive spikes – then, the largest cumulative number of confirmed COVID-19 infections in Southeast Asia – a nationwide Movement of Control Order (MCO) was promulgated on 16th March 2020, that eventually with the Conditional MCO, also cover the federal territory island of Labuan.

Across the South China Sea, in the month of September 2020, public health experts sounded the alarm that the coronavirus may have begun to reside not only in, but beyond, Sabah where outbreaks initially started at a police lock-up and prison in the east coast, had began to spread to Sarawak, and the rest of the country in peninsular Malaysia.

IN THE BEGINNING

With the intrusion of British colonialism into then Malaya in the 19th. century, the introduction of rubber to Singapore in 1877 via Brazil, Kew Gardens in London and Sri Lanka that within a decade after it was introduced, slash-and-burn local farmers in this part of Southeast Asia planted the Devil’s Milk trees (“dripping from head to foot, from every pore, with blood and dirt” as the most adept in describing the long, grim history of rubber) to become the replacement to their subsistence crops. The tale of how one Henry Wickham purloined Brazil’s rubber patrimony is one of the romantic legends of the British Empire. By his own account, in 1876 Wickham collected over 70,000 hevea seeds from the forests along the Tapajós River. Then, he smuggled the seeds to Joseph Hooker, the eminent botanist who served as director of the Royal Botanic Gardens.

By the 1930s, Malaysia produced half of the world’s rubber. Majority of the Chinese and Indians that live in Malaysia today are descendants of coolie and indenture laborers brought to work on these rubber plantations which were owned by Guthrie, Sime Darby and Golden Hope until they were, in a bout of economic nationalism, taken over in a dawn raid in 1981. They helped transform Malaysia into Britain’s richest colony,whereas in the 1990s, a typical rubber tapper, who spent six hours a day tapping 400 trees, made just about RM$131 a month, and even with the increase of rubber production due to Covid19, 2.25 million people or an average of five people per family, who live off the commodity, these smallholders still live below the poverty line income that was only recently revised from a monthly household income of RM980 to RM2,208.

At times, we wonder whether the country has progress because decades ago, the Guyanese scholar Walter Rodney sketched adroitly How Europe Underdeveloped Africa where human bondage was the driving and animating force of this abject horror in survival.

England had, at one period of time, a 33 percent share of the slave trade in the Caribbean around 1673, and 74 percent by 1683. Of that dreadful total, the Royal African Company, under the thumb of the Crown, held a hefty 90 percent share in 1690.

As scholar William Pettigrew has argued forcefully, the African slave trade rested at the heart of what is still held dear in capitalist societies: free trade, anti-monarchism, and a racially sharpened and class-based democracy.

BIG PLANTATIONS BIG PROBLEMS

The replacement of subsistence crops to plantation-estate type of capitalist agriculture presupposes a division of industrialized town and the rural countryside that inadvertently infertile the soil in the interest of fertilizing producers’ profits. This mode in capitalist production was accompanied by profound ecological degradation. Indeed, Marx had warned that the development of productive forces and technology under capitalist relations of production does not automatically prepare the conditions for human emancipation, but on the contrary, causes a deep alienation of human beings from their environment in the form of a “metabolic rift”, that is, there would be an ecological disruption in their interrelations with nature, (John Bellamy Foster, Marx’s Ecology, New York: Monthly Review Press, 2000).

Owing to an unequal ecological exchange – by redirecting the Big Farms’ industrial agriculture in the Global North to the Global South – it had instigated developing national bodies in stripping local resources by state-led government-link companies (GLCs) hitching onto ventures (like taking over titleless cultivators land or opening up FELDA frontier-plantations but indebting the settlers or the settleless minority communities in Sabah and Sarawak still unsettled after their timberland has been deforested by commercial loggers) that impoverished the marginalised populace. The underdevelopment of development in Sabah and Sarawak is explored in another study, whereas FELDA’s proletariats effort is snuffed out by corporate capital FVG in collusion with monopoly capital plantation and oil conglomerates.

In a sense, the Big Farms of corporatised agricultural entities enable, through the circuit of capital under late imperialism period of globalization, the etiology of disease via agribusiness. The zoonotic diseases (or zoonoses) such as SARS, MERS, and H1N1 transmitted to humans from nonhuman animals, wild or domesticated; they are assisted by these Big Farms deforestation of virgin terrains to plant commercially high-yielding crops, including durians. Pandemics in the contemporary global economy are connected to the circuits of capital – Global North opening up “commodity corridors” planting coffee trees and soya plants in South America for instances or the palm-oil plantations along the Kalimantan-Sarawak borders as another example that are rapidly changing environmental conditions – a consequential ecological-epidemiological resultant is the imminent propogation of the COVID-19 pandemic.

The dire consequence is that forest disease dynamics, the pathogens’ primeval sources, are no longer restricted to the hinterlands of semi-urban or kampung-kampung villages alone. Their associated epidemiologies have spread across time and into space where every pathogenic SARS carrier bat from Batu Caves could easily leeches on abang or adik in the federal capital of Kuala Lumpur a flight minute away.

More outlooks and outcomes can be found in COVID-19 and Circuits of Capital (by Rob Wallace, Alex Liebman, Luis Fernando Chaves, and Rodrick Wallace) in the May 2020 issue of Monthly Review.

THE ECONOMY

Six plus decades after an independence gained from British colonial master, the country still rests on a neo-liberal economic platform which is supply chaining-latched to transnational corporations that, with the onslaught of the COVID-19 pandemic, has only accentuated the inter-connection of ecological, epidemiological, and economic vulnerabilities as imposed by monopoly capitalism. This is because the transnational corporation is not only a product but the process of concentration and centralization of capital that had created monopoly capital itself. The accumulation of capital has always meant expansion – commercially and politically. This process of growing and spreading, on a global scope and along corporate scale, has an imperialistic in its characteristics besides the rather deep qualitative transformation in the organization and dominance of monopoly capital on the exploitation of peripheral countries’ natural resources and the comparative advantages derived from global labour arbitrage through the
continuation of significant wage differentials between various countries in different geographical regions. These binary processes deepen the opening of financialization capitalism in penetrated state-regimes.This restructuring of monopoly capital on a wide-world scale has given contemporary imperialism a new dimensional appearance under emergence of the Covid19 scenario, (Foster and Suwandi, COVID-19 and Catastrophe Capitalism, Commodity Chains and Ecological-Epidemiological-Economic Crises, Monthly Review, June 2020). Now through the inexorable expansion of human activities – commercial logging, fossil fuel exploration, industrial land development, extensive extension in highway construction and urbanisation in general – these wildlife species carrying pathogens have come much closer in contact to human beings.

MALAYSIA has been a place where many, and large, fortunes were amassed. Whereas the majority of businesses built during the prewar period were found in the tin and rubber industries that comprised illustrious family firms built by Low Yat, Loke Yew, Chong Yoke Choy, H.S, Lee, Tan Chay Yan and Lau Pak Khuan who collude with colonial British plantation interests to build their empires, the “new money-capital” entities like YTL Corp’s Yeoh Tiong Lay, Berjaya’s Vincent Tan, Genting’s Lim Goh Tong, Sunway’s Jeffrey Cheah, Lion’s William Cheng and the Ananda Krishnan groups and business stables attempted the forging of more Sino-Indo-Malay corporations, that is, a co-opetition strategy whereby Chinese and Indian capitals can compete as well as co-operate with Malay interests. Those Kuoks, Tehs and Queks were the pioneers in the sugar and palm oil, property and banking sectors during the British Empire, whereas the YTLs’ and Berjayas’ and Annans’ were maintained and retained by transnational connections in the post-independence neo-colonialism period, and the GLCs (government-linked companies) and NGCs (non-government corporations) formulated were sustained with and by various ethnocracy kleptocratic regimes since.

On 18th August 2020, Top Glove Corp Bhd became the second most valuable stock on Bursa Malaysia, having displaced Public Bank Bhd. Now, the gap between Top Glove and the local bourse’s No. 1 spot Malayan Banking Bhd (Maybank) is narrower than ever. At the closing bell on Wednesday, 21st October 2020, Top Glove’s shares gained 4.06 per cent to RM27.14 with 26.13 million units traded, pushing its market capitalisation (market cap) to RM73.47 billion.

Yet at a time of overall national calamity, a convergence of ecological, pandemic and economic proportions, Knight Frank estimates Malaysia capital accumulation of wealth-creation is the 10th fastest in the world – while the mean income was RM$7,901 last year – the firm’s 2020 Wealth Report projects that the number of Malaysians with more than US$30 million will swell by 35 percent between 2019 and 2024, compared with mere 2 per cent between 2018 and 2019. This is happening during a shift in economic activity from manufacturing production to more financial activities – where business focuses on financial transactions and stock-share tradings – that often generate higher private rewards disproportionate to their social productivity according to Nobel Prize economist, James Tobin.

One central aspect of this observed phenomenon lies in the insurgence of financialization capitalism in operation – which primarily embraces finance, insurance and real estate transactions (FIRE) – where the surplus value, that is, the added value created by workers in excess of their own labor-cost is being appropriated by the new financial capitalists as profits, (Marx, The Capital, chapter 8). This surplus value as the source of society’s accumulation of fund or investment of fund, part of is re-invested, but part of it appropriated as personal income, and used for consumption purposes by the owners of capital assets. The workers cannot capture this benefit directly because they have no claim to the means of financial creation or its final production.
Firms would likely be choosing to invest in real estate and other forms of financial assets rather than in productive capital, and would even migrate to other places wherever the unit of labour cost is lower (Lim Mah Hui, Globalization, Export-led growth and inequality: The East Asian Story, South Centre, November 2014). This is an instance when transnational corporations, and even indigenous capital, will seek to lower and suppress the wage of labour, and also directly increase their profits by uploading to Global North the capital onto a new company listed overseas or through schemes with transfer pricing elements.

To desert from production when its share price is rising, Top Grove intends to open its second overseas accounts in Hong Kong, besides Singapore, even when its engendered market capitalisation during this year (+RM$70 billion) is profoundly more than enough to upgrade, or build new, production plants, without necessarily seeking for more investors fund, (theedgemarkets.com October 2020). At US$1 billion, Top Glove’s listing would be the biggest ever by a Malaysian company in Hong Kong, according to data compiled by Bloomberg. Meanwhile, the firm has also earmarked RM3 billion for CAPEX to build 450 new lines, creating new capacity of 60 billion pieces of gloves from CY2020 to CY2026.

The quantum leap on the quarterly net profits of two glove makers — Hartalega Holdings Bhd and Supermax Corp Bhd — is just eye-popping.

Hartalega’s net profit jumped five times to a record high of RM544.96 million in the second financial quarter ended Sept 30, 2020 (2QFY21) from RM103.87 million a year ago, an evidence of the strongest-ever demand for disposable rubber gloves as a result of the Covid-19 pandemic.

With an upsurge of demand for gloves from every part of the world, this is not something unusual with the emergence of the Covid19. In the past, “We have had demand coming from specific countries but right now we are having requests for gloves in almost every corner of the world” in an interview with Bloomberg TV recently, Top Glove managing director Lee Kim Meow said.
He further indicates that the demand for gloves used to be about 8.0 per cent to 12 per cent before the Covid-19 pandemic but now the glove manufacturer was seeing the loop had increased by 250 per cent like in the United States, and 300 per cent in some European countries as well as Japan. Even if USA temporarily ban the import of the Top Glove products owing to complains by production workers’ recruitment procedures and employment conditions, its executive chairman had this to say “We have other plans as well if the U.S. does not allow the shipment to enter into their country,” he added, citing Brazil, which now has the second most confirmed COVID-19 cases in the world, as one potential alternative.
Voa news 17 July 2020.

According to Business Today dated 11 June 2020, Top Glove achieves record-breaking net profit of RM 350 million.

With Covid19, within a short span of 6 months, the glove production companies, but not the rubber small holding families, had produced 5 billionaires in the country from this fraternity cohort of capitalists.

Another example on consumption purposes by the owners of capital assets can be seen by the seven top 10 highest-paid boards of the companies in Malaysia who are family-controlled companies; also where the top 10 highest-paid chief executive officers (CEOs) are mainly residence-members in these boards.

Indeed, the six major GLCs are Malayan Banking Bhd (Maybank), CIMB Group Holdings Bhd, Sapura Energy Bhd, Sime Darby Plantation Bhd, Telekom Malaysia Bhd (TM) and Axiata Group Bhd. The remaining four among the top 10 boards with the highest total non-executive director pay are AMMB Holdings Bhd, Public Bank Bhd, IHH Healthcare Bhd and PPB Group Bhd.

Those were among the main findings in the SecuritiesCommission Corporate Governance Monitor 2020 (CG Monitor 2020)

Further details on corporate capital and coronavirus infecting wealth via infusing government linked companies and the non-government corporations activities can be seen in these corporations consisting of banking institutions and fund management entities: https://firesstorms.wordpress.com/2020/10/06/corporate-capital-with-coronavirus/

With the MCO in place, the leading economic indicators are pointing to the sharpest contraction since the 1998 Asian Financial Crisis recession. With the economy being affected by the COVID-19 pandemic and the implementation of Movement Control Order (MCO), there was a contraction of 17.1% by the 2nd quarter (2Q20) already, [channelasianews @2:00pm 14th August 2020].

Central bank governor Nor Shamsiah Yunus, Bank Negara Malaysia, said that the sectors worst hit by the pandemic were tourism, manufacturing and investment. On a seasonally adjusted quarterly basis, the economy shrank by 16.5 percent, the worst contraction since the series began in the second quarter 2000. In fact, Fitch Solutions (South East Asia, October 2020) offer this advice:

The government remains bound by fiscal constraints, leaving monetary policy as the main tool to support growth.

The country is in dire present and imminent economic crises because her External Debt had increased to RM$1,002,956 Million in the second quarter of 2020 from RM$975,907 Million in the first quarter of 2020, with a projected RM$1.26 Trillion by year end.

Norway and Malaysia began oil and gas exploration at about same time, both having the same size of hydrocarbon reserves, but while Norway managed her national bounty carefully and admirably to hold one of the world’s largest sovereign funds from O&G development – exceeding one trillion USD in value – Malaysia has a national debt exceeding one trillion, and rising, likely upsurging to RM$1.26T by end of 2020.

Together with Slower recovery seen in Malaysia’s labour market Tan Siew Mung in theedgemarkets.com, and the inadequacy in the packaged economic stimuli where as a comparison, the stimuli packages unveiled during the Global Financial Crisis in 2008-2009 amounted to RM67 billion (or 8.4 per cent of GDP) – more than three times larger than the planned RM20 billion (only about 1.4 per cent of GDP) presently.

Amongst the small manufacturing enterprises, the Malaysian economy is amongst the most highly exposed economies in the region to both Chinese demand and supply. China is Malaysia’s number one trading partner, a large source of foreign investments, and its top tourist source outside of ASEAN.

Additionally, over the past decade, Malaysian firms have become amongst the most deeply integrated in the global production networks. This is compounded by the fact that regional supply chains have become increasingly China-centric. Indeed, more than a quarter of Malaysia-China trade (about US$20 billion in 2018) is made up of intermediate components – exactly the kind of products that gets affected the most when global supply chains are disrupted.

The enmeshed and closely linked supply chain is one aspect in modern economy. It used to be closely related to the Global North exploiting precarious labour in Global South as part of monopoly-capital dimension. Now that the Malaysia dependence on China’s trade is so preciously interwined that its diplomacy with China is one of acceptance and adaptation, especially to the South China Sea territorial and maritime issues.

The Domestic Trade and Consumer Affairs Ministry (KPDNHEP) received 20,572 complaints and inquiries since the Movement Control Order (MCO) that began on March 18, 2020.

The exceptional dizzily profit-taking by selective firms, and the gorging of operational expenses by those politically-appointed in the GLCs and NGCs, and an extraordinary high national debts (where government employees still think that Petronas oil is gushing from the earth endlessly and that fiscal helicopters shall continuously drop ringgits month after month) coupled with high unemployment in the private sector where precarious workers are seeking in the gig economy as Grab drivers or Panda food delivers, the economy – and the political – fallouts cannot be stably maintained.

Thus, when the backdoor regime premier attempted to request the Agung to proclaim a State of Emergency to avoid a sitting of Parliament to approve Budget 2021 on November 6th. – when he could possibly be out-voted to resign – the kleptocrates, capital holders, a prince and ordinary people raged that it would be the “last nail to the economy coffin” (see APPENDIX C). It is not unexpected because the Malaysian economy is no more an industrial-based but anchored upon since 1983 on a capital-market system (Jomo Sundram and Tan Wooi SynPrivatization and re-nationalization in Malaysia – a Survey, an unpublished working paper, 2005). It leads to the emergence to, and the pervasion of, financialization capitalism in Malaysia.

State investment vehicles had been used as conduits in the promotion of financialization capitalism like Pernas (Perbadanan Nasional Berhad – the National Corporation set up in 1969) and PNB (Permodalan Nasional Berhad – National Equity Corporation established in 1978), the former that bought Chinese and foreign (mainly British) owned companies, the latter transferred shares held by government to individual bumiputera shareholders. PNB becomes eventually the second biggest institutional investor after state-run Employees Provident Fund (EPF) and has accumulated deposits, even way back in 2008, of RM$120 billion (25% of GNP, then).

The second key point is that the rise of a ‘mass investment culture’ – where anyone can buy unit trusts, government bonds, debt-financed share buybacks, brownfield portfolio investments and other esoteric financial instruments – has strengthened the ‘dominance of finance capital’ (Harmes 2001, Mass investment culture?, New Left Review, 9, pp 103-24), where “even ordinary households had become financialized, too”, (Costas LapavitsasFinancialised Capitalism: Crisis and Financial Expropriation, Historical Materialism 17 (2009), School of Oriental and African Studies, London).

Thirdly, there are data supporting the assertion that enterprises are profiting from financialization capitalism, and such financial profits represents a vast public subsidy to the financial system characteristic of financialization capitalism model. Indeed, it is the management of the public rate of interest by the central bank (keeping the rate very low) has created increasing room for the capitalist class as a whole privately to appropriate profits, even when there is stagnant rate of profit across the economy.

Therefore, the daunting task going forward is challenging in that it shall require prudent economic management to gradually wind down some of these stimulus measures and move towards a more targeted approach to help those that are particularly vulnerable, as well as look at rebuilding the country’s fiscal space and balances to prepare for the next crisis, (World Bank, 2020). Another consultancy firm, the FitchSolutions has this to say: the economy is still under heavy downside pressure from the Covid-19 pandemic and the nascent recovery following the deep contraction in 2Q20 remains vulnerable and will require more policy support – that may well be for corporate capital gain, again.

With the gathering cloud of political instability laid out from foreseen post GE14 PH governance, and the unstable PN government that may be challenged anytime, whether it is due to administrative incompetency and or persistent corrupt practices, the political dynamics of a Covid19 economy need to be unpacked for a lightning analysis.

THE POLITICS

The governing regimes – from independence in 1957 to pre-GE14 2018 – ruled in the grey zone between competitive electoral partial democracy and ‘full’ authoritarianism with naked repression. Through a process in organizing periodic elections they tried to obtain at least a semblance of democratic legitimacy, hoping to satisfy external as well as internal actors. At the same time, by placing those elections under tight authoritarian controls, they try to cement their continued hold on hegemonic power. These elections are inclusive and pluralistic, yet may not fully competitive nor truly democratic but at least such elections would be perceived by opposition parties as not likely doomed to lose.

1. POST-GE14

With the intensified coaltion of varied political parties and civil society forces and the adoption and applied usage of new media, the suceeding Pakatan Harapan (PH) was able to erode legitimacy of the ruling regime consisting of United Malays National Organization (UMNO) and other parties of the ruling coalition and the theological-political party: Islamist Pan-Malaysian Islamic Party (Parti Islam SeMalaysia or PAS). According to Brown (‘Federal and State Elections’, 743), the estimated swing to opposition parties in West Malaysia was 58.5% among Indians and 21.7% among Chinese voters; 4.6% of Malay voters switched their support to the opposition.

Fauzi had expressed that it is of more than symbolic importance that the once pro-Anwar faction in PAS which morphed into Amanah was also known as the ‘Erdogan faction’. Hence, PH is not short of second-generation Islamists whose roots may be traced back to PAS or Islamist NGOs such as Ikram and ABIM. Indeed, in Dr Mahathir’s post-GE14 cabinet, Amanah leaders have been entrusted to helm strategic ministries. Amanah president who was also former PAS deputy president, Mohamad Sabu, is now minister of defence; Salahuddin Ayub, its deputy president and a former PAS vice president, is presently minister of agriculture and agro-based industry; Dr Dzulkefly Ahmad, a former University of Science Malaysia scientist who held strategic posts for both PAS and later Amanah, is currently minister of health. Bersatu rookie, Dr Maszlee Malik, a former IIUM political scientist with an Ikram-activist background, helms the education ministry. Dr Mujahid Yusof Rawa, another Amanah vice president and son of PAS’s first Murshid al-’Am during its leadership-by-ulama (kepimpinan ulama) era in the early 1980s, took his oath on 2 July 2018 as religious affairs minister at the Prime Minister’s Department. Khalid Samad, a controversial former PAS leader once touted as a radical Islamist during his student days in the United Kingdom in the 1970s, becomes the Federal Territory minister.

2. IMPACT OF PAS-UMNO PACT

On 14 September 2019, Malay-based opposition parties UMNO (United Malays National Organization) and PAS (Islamic Party of Malaysia) signed a National Consensus Charter to formalize political co-operation. The agreement seeks to ride on Malay-Muslim unhappiness towards the PH (Alliance of Hope) government which these two parties claim to be dominated by the secular and Chinese DAP (Democratic Action Party). The UMNO and PAS informal cooperation since 2018 has resulted in some positive outcome for the opposition: they won three consecutive by-elections in Malay-dominated constituencies in 2019 ( with an alternative view here); the PH government was pressured to reverse some of its policies including ratification of ICERD (International Convention on the Elimination of All Forms of Racial Discrimination) and withdrawal from the Rome Statute of the International Criminal Court. Further, the PH government was under an undercurrent towed to implement populist policies such as the introduction of Jawi calligraphy in vernacular schools, and taking a neutral stance towards a controversial Indian preacher Zakir Naik, in order to appease the Malay-Muslim electorate. On one angle, one may argue that the warlords at UMNO divisional-level is already fragmenting the effectiveness in this UMNO-PAS positioning, and might have even diffused the overall effectiveness of the new pact by alienating reformers within UMNO itself. One may argue that the pact has, in a limited way, cripple the already fragile BN (National Front) coalition. This posturing could even dilute the importance of MCA (Malaysian Chinese Association) and MIC (Malaysian Indian Congress) political partnership in the long-term.

3. THE SHERATON MOVE

However, PH only ruled only for 22 months before being replaced by a new Government named Perikatan Nasional, a coalition led by Muhyiddin Yassin after Bersatu left the Pakatan Harapan coalition together with ex-PKR members to join with Barisan Nasional (BN) , Malaysian Islamic Party (PAS) and Gabungan Parti Sarawak.

Muhyiddin brought down the reformist Pakatan Harapan government by pulling 26 of his Malaysian United Indigenous Party (Bersatu) MPs out of the ruling coalition, who were joined by 10 more from Anwar Ibrahim’s People’s Justice Party (Parti Keadilan Rakyat – PKR).

The “Sheraton Move” got its name from the Sheraton hotel in Petaling Jaya, Selangor where several prominent factions within PH had a clandestine meeting with leaders of the then Opposition Barisan Nasional (BN) in February 2020 that subsequently led to the formation of a new government under Bersatu president Tan Sri Muhyiddin Yassin in March, 2020.

It was regarded by some insiders as discontent and disagreement, and the continuous infighting among old guards whose differences with other players never ended for the past 20 to 30 years. The hidden conflict also had allowed for the oppositions to exploit that disagreement and discontent among one another.

According to Syed Saddiq in a bfm.my podcast, he did not support Bersatu’s decision to pull out from PH no matter how unpopular they stood to become among the Malays. “We should not have used that as an excuse to backstab our partners to then leave Harapan and to align ourselves with the enemies who we seek to challenge and confront,” he said.

The other version of this intriguing backstage manoeuvre is told by Adam Mukhriz Mohd Muhayeddin who related that the plot began unfolding in earnest on the fateful Sunday of February 23, after what appeared to be an uneventful PH presidential council meeting on the (previous) Friday ……….While Azmin’s ‘Cartel’ met at Sheraton, Bersatu held a supreme council meeting when in that meeting, Tun had refused to accept UMNO (en bloc) as a component……Adam went on to assert that Dr Mahathir resigned as the PM because he did not want to lead the coalition that later became Perikatan Nasional….That set in motion events that ultimately prevented Dr Mahathir from showing his majority support to the Agong as he could no longer count PH’s 92 lawmakers in his camp. He later would attempt to convene a special parliamentary sitting to resolve the impasse, but the Speaker refused, culminating in Muhyddin being sworn in as the eighth prime minister.

To many observers, the former premier’s shenanigans cannot hide behind the curtain that he had a director’s role behind the shooting scene.

4. MUYHIDDIN GOVERNMENT

The Muhyiddin cabinet was formed on 10 March 2020, nine days after Muhyiddin Yassin was appointed as the 8th Prime Minister of Malaysia. Immediate measures were to address the Covid-19 pandemic and the immediate challenges, prompting the government to swiftly allocate huge funds to cushion the economic impact. However, these suite of fiscal payouts would not erase the looming politico-socioecononic problems confronting the country: the Sabah State elections 2020, the emerging Covid19 admist that election campaigns and thenceafter when spikes prevailed in Sabah and in the state of Selangor, besides frequent reservoir water being pollutant-contaminated and the not infrequent preventive water supply shutdowns in the Klang Valley during his ineffective administration – a perceived inability felt by rakyat2 to manage the country wellbeing efficiently.

Muhyiddin as head of an ad hoc coalition comprising Bersatu, Umno/Barisan Nasional, the Malaysian Islamic Party and regional parties from Sarawak and Sabah that commands only a wafer-thin majority of 113 in the country’s 222-member parliament. While the new parliamentary speaker installed by Muhyiddin in July has intimated that he will keep motions of no-confidence at the bottom of agenda, the prime minister is fearful of an ambush during the five week-long budget debate set to begin on November 9, 2020. In fact, if there is a possibly whereby every opposition MP were to turn up to vote against his budget, the absence of a mere six government parliamentarians would see the budget defeated and Muhyiddin ousted. Therefore, a failure to pass such a “supply bill” is equivalent to a loss of confidence under Malaysia’s parliamentary system. His probable threat may come from within because Umno – the coalition’s largest partner with 39 seats to Bersatu’s 32 – is bitter regarding the unequal sharing of cabinet posts among the enlarged 72-member frontbench: Bersatu having 26 of the ministerial-level jobs while Umno has only 17 posts.

5. STATE OF EMERGENCY

Malaysia will move backwards if a state of emergency is declared at a time when the country needs strong leadership to steer it in the right direction, Opposition leader Datuk Seri Anwar Ibrahim said.

Tan Sri Muhyiddin’s Perikatan Nasional government could lose a vote in Parliament if just three out of its 113 MPs defect; thus, when the Malaysian Cabinet ministers on Saturday (Oct 24) defended their decision to seek emergency powers on Friday, amid criticism from the opposition and civil society over what some are calling an undemocratic move by the Muhyiddin administration to stay in power, there was a call by civil activists to consider the 6-point multi-party deal by reconfiguring politics as proposed in June 2020.

Indeed, Wong Chin-Huat in a South China Morning Post piece on 24th. October 2020 contends on why Malaysia needs a ‘confidence and supply’ government, not a state of emergency, expressing verbatim:

_If PM Muhyiddin Yassin can get the support of 40 or more opposition MPs, coalition partner Umno’s 39 seats would lose their blackmail power._
_A confidence and supply arrangement would produce a stable government scrutinised with the strongest ever opposition, argues Wong Chin Huat._

How can this political stalemate be resolved in such a way that both the government and opposition are functioning? Muhyiddin, and Malaysia, have four options … Wong Chin Huat articulated.

Malaysia is paying a heavy price as the country’s politicians – amid a global pandemic and looming recession – compete for top jobs by breaking and reforming alliances rather than focusing on policy.

First is fresh elections – the option favoured by Umno and the Malaysian Islamic Party, which are expected to do well at the expense of Bersatu in such a scenario. This option has been completely ruled out after the Sabah state elections were blamed for the country’s recent spike in coronavirus cases, but even if the polls were to go ahead, party-hopping may still continue afterwards.

The second option is an expansion of government to include more Umno ministers, or to form a government of national unity – both of which would merely postpone its inevitable implosion as supposed allies continue to sabotage each other while awaiting the next general elections.

Third on the list is a state of emergency, which would rule out fresh polls and be tantamount to an open admission by the prime minister that he has lost control of his own government. Such a “self-coup” would not only be economically costly as markets panic and investors withdraw, but would likely trigger mass protests such as those seen in Thailand and Indonesia.

The fourth option is a “confidence and supply agreement” with the ousted Pakatan Harapan coalition, which has failed to gather a new majority and also does not want fresh polls.

A confidence and supply government would be a completely new chapter for Malaysia’s democracy: a stable scrutinised with the strongest ever opposition in an empowered parliament. As long as Muhyiddin can get support from 40 or more opposition MPs on confidence and the budget, Umno’s 39 seats would lose their blackmail power.

To secure such an agreement, Muhyiddin would have to concede to some key reforms, but why not if this can let him complete his term? He should act rationally, even if just for his own self-interest.

Otherwise, the call for an Emergency promulgation by the Palace is undemocratic, uncivil to political stability, disruptive to the national economy and unconstitutional, see various outbursts from different actors in this wayangkulit under the Appendices below:

THE COVID19 THE ECONOMICS AND THE POLITICS

The coronavirus Covid19 will not go away. It will not move on overnight. It will not miraculously disappear. If anything’s matters, this virus shall be with us until a vaccine is deployed for mass inoculation, and the mode in capitalist production changes. Through the inexorable expansion in human activities – timber logging, fossil fuel exploration, highway construction and urbanisation in general – wildlife species carrying these pathogens are closing-in-contact to human beings. Covid19, and other zoonotic variants, shall exist because monopoly capitalism has introduced, and ensure, interlocking supply chains connecting various vendors’ hubs to deploy raw materials from Global South to Global South for intermediate processing through the advantages of labour arbitrage before dispatching finished products or processed data to Global North for final consumption; contaminated, and infected fish from Vietnam coastline can introduce epidemiological diseases to a trawler landing in Darwin. Monopoly capitalism shall continue to ensure global imperialism to extend Global North’s Big Farms into Global South’s terrains where zoonotic diseases shall migrate through transborder checkpoints to route coronavirus to different domains on planet Earth.

The economics‘s financialization capitalism shall reach its height durimg this Covid19 pandemic because various stimulus packages have enriched corporate capital to invest or speculate in financial transactions than to produce physical goods; the extracted surplus value is higher, and faster, to gain than retaining or returning to the laborious manufacting processes that require multi-stages activities prior to outputting finished goods. The central banking digital currency (BCDC) will hasten the thrust, and width, in digital formation and transaction. In the process, this new imperial-capital mode shall introduce new norms to digital labour whom shall be precariously endangered in their cyber workplaces as never before – changing the way they work, changing the way they interact with fellow cybertariats and humanoids, changing the way they think about their earned yet extracted surplus values which are foregone in a new capitalistic-environmental workspace.

The politics of Covid19 shall “infect” coronavirusness corporate capital and politicians enriching the former because new digital domains have enlarged scales to broaden the widening scope in a variety of financial systems and models to enable quicker returns on investment with innovative digital finance instruments to exploit; and the latter politicians shall wander in wonder of the coronavirus infecting them, and entrapping themselves in an e-economy that they do not know how to conform nor what to confront. Would a wandering or hopping or whopping politician be able to serve rakyats but be serfs to the new enligthened generation of awaken and proletarianized voters?

BIBLIOGRAPHY

Andreas Ufen,

GIGA German Institute of Global and Area Studies, Institute of Asian Studies, Hamburg,Germany

The transformation of political party opposition in Malaysia and its implications for the electoral authoritarian regime

Ahmad Fauzi Abdul Hamid

Development in the Post-Colonial State: Class, Capitalism and the Islamist Political Alternative in Malaysia

Ahmad Fauzi Abdul Hamid and Zawawi Ibrahim

The Governance of Religious Diversity in Malaysia: Islam in a Secular State or Secularism in an Islamic State?

John Bellamy Foster and Intan Suwandi

Covid19 and Catastrophe Capitalism – commodity Chains and Ecological-Epidemiological-Economic Crises

Jaclyn Ling-Chien Neo, Malay Nationalism, Islamic Supremacy and the Constitutional Bargain in the Multi-ethnic Composition of Malaysia

Wong Chin-Huat

https://www.scmp.com/week-asia/opinion/article/3106919/why-malaysia-needs-confidence-and-supply-government-not-state

DR MAHATHIR BIN MOHAMAD

http://chedet.cc/?p=3196

APPENDIX: A

Political Developments May Be Moving Fast

 

The mistakes that many analysts are making is that they tend to lump Umno as one group when only about 10 MPs of Team A (out of 39 MPs) are in favour of a ceasefire deal with Bersatu/PM. Umno Youth leader Asyraf and Zahid may be the ones coming out with public statements about making peace with Bersatu etc. for the sake of the country but the sentiments of other UMNO leaders and the grassroot members may tell a different story.

 

Whatever “ceasefire or no-fire or campfire” deals that Zahid and Asyraf (of Team A) may be making with Bersatu/PM, they have little legitimacy, as they (Team A) cannot speak for the whole of Umno (esp. MPs) but only the corrupted ones, who are all being charged or about to be charged in court.

 

In fact, the so-called ceasefire, which could be seen as Another capitulation to Bersatu, may be worsening the situation internally in Umno and angering many Umno MPs (nearly 25 of them). The tension between Berstau & Umno in the states of Sabah, Perak and Johor could also implode at any time, putting pressure at co-operation at the federal level.

 

PM must know that his majority in Parliament is getting weaker by the day and UNSUSTAINABLE. When a man is in an unstable and vulnerable position like in a quick sand situation, the more he moves out of desperation, the quicker he is sucked into the sand.

 

There is talk that the King may step in to direct or decree the speaker of Dewan Rakyat to allow for a vote on the motion of no confidence as soon as possible as he (King) and the public would like to know if the current PM still commands a simple majority. This Right of the King and the public to know is so fundamental to our parliamentary democracy.

Based on various developments taking place which we can expect that the King is monitoring closely, the King may have reasons to believe or suspect that the PM no longer enjoys the support of a majority of MPs and he would naturally like the August House to confirm if it is true or not.
 
Most possible outcome would be that once the PM is aware that there is going to be a vote of no confidence against him and that he is likely to lose, he would be expected to quickly throw in the towel before 2 November and call it a day. Heard rumours that his doctor and family are very concerned that any undue stress could be lethal for him in his current recovery from pancreatic cancer.
 
If PM were to resign soon, the responsible and wise King, even if he is advised otherwise by the outgoing PM, would most likely Not go for a dissolution of Parliament, therefore, a Snap Election is most UNLIKELY.

The King may prologue or temporarily suspend Parliament (to maintain political stability) but he would appoint a new PM first, which is likely to be Ku Li due to his Integrity and Competence and that he is also seen as a “compromise” gentleman candidate acceptable to all key players. The King may already have such information and may already be convinced that Ku Li would be able to command a strong and stable majority in Dewan Rakyat.
 
Some anti-national mischief makers and devious, pro-corruption & pro-kleptocratic bloggers (such as RKP) are spreading fear and rumours that if the current PM were to be forced to resign (even legitimately), there would be one or more of the following:
 
–         snap election

–         massive social unrest and instability

–         martial law and declaration of a state of emergency by the King
 
Basically a possible collapse of our civil society. This is an insult to the Rakyat of Malaysia that they are so immature, uncivilized and violence prone that they cannot accept a legitimate and peaceful change of government during a crisis. These traitors of our country must be exposed and be proven wrong.

APPENDIX: B

STATE OF EMERGENCY

  1. Covid-19 has been used to justify Parliament being delayed, shortened and void of any debates.
  2. Now it is to justify declaring a State of Emergency. But the power and authority in today’s Government have been adequate to deal with the pandemic.
  3. We don’t find the kind of objection by the people as seen in the US and Europe. Our people have very largely obeyed the restrictions such as the MCO.
  4. What can Emergency do to stop the pandemic more than what we can do now. Nothing.
  5. But an Emergency would give extra power to the Prime Minister. What he has done so far has not mitigated the political, economic and social problems affecting the country.
  6. He has a huge Cabinet which has contributed nothing to the well-being of the people and the country.
  7. Most of the things done is about the political situation. This Government is not the Government elected by the people. It has come to power by undemocratic means. And now it is only concerned about staying in power.
  8. Faced with the possibility of being overthrown, the Prime Minister wants the powers under a state of Emergency. The only benefit would accrue to the Prime Minister, as Parliament would be paralysed. He would claim that it is the wish of the Palace.
  9. Already, the mere rumour of an emergency has resulted in the stock market taking a deep dive.
  10. If Emergency is declared then the market will collapse completely. The investors have no faith in the Prime Minister being able to manage the economy.
  11. He messed up the Covid-19 situation by trying to grab the Government of Sabah. The present spike is entirely due to the Sabah elections.
  12. So, the Government has been changed. What good has it brought to Sabah.
  13. Countries with more severe Covid-19 problems have not declared emergency for the whole country but only for the affected areas.
  14. That was specific for dealing with the local problem. But none have suspended laws and Parliament as it would if Emergency is declared in Malaysia.
  15. There are no riots or violence in Malaysia, no breakdown of laws and order to justify an Emergency.
  16. But there is a need for some changes to be made to the Government which seized power through undemocratic means.

DR MAHATHIR BIN MOHAMAD

.

APPENDIX: C

24 October 2020 – Press Statement by Tengku Razaleigh Hamzah

Proposed Emergency May Put The Final Nail In The Coffin Of Our Economy

1)    The Covid Pandemic has caused so much pain, distress and suffering to the man-on-the-street and it breaks my heart every time I hear or read stories on how the ordinary Rakyat are struggling and coping with the crisis.

2)    Every day, more and more businesses, big and small, are closing down. More people are getting laid off and unemployed. For the many self-employed consultants and contractors, there is hardly any work out there for them. Yet, they somehow have to feed and provide the basic necessities for themselves and their families.

3)    When the pandemic first started, there seemed to be some determination by the Government to control the spread of the disease and to provide the necessary healthcare and treatment needed for the patients concerned. Financial aid was right provided. The front line workers and the civil servants are still doing a good job, even now, in providing the services needed.

4)    Over time and lately, there seems to be a lack of a coordinated and integrated approach in dealing with the crisis in what appears to be a lack of clear and exemplary leadership by the Government. There are also double standards on the enforcement and penalty meted out, one for the ordinary Rakyat and another for government ministers and well connected people. Even on the procurement of the much-needed Covid vaccines for our people from overseas, the Government has taken a narrow, short-sighted and irresponsible approach of not supporting any genuine private sector initiatives, knowing full well that it would cost the Government nothing but would increase the chances of our country getting a workable vaccine when it is ready.

5)    As I have reasons to believe that the Prime Minister (and his Cabinet) no longer commands the support of a majority of the Dewan Rakyat and has therefore, lost his legitimacy, I have recently written to the Speaker of Dewan Rakyat to treat a “motion of no confidence” as a matter of priority to be debated and voted on at the earliest possible opportunity. This is in line with the principles of our Parliamentary System of Democracy, which the Constitution is supreme and above that of the Standing Orders and the authority of the House is far above that of a government minister. My initiative with the Speaker, should not be seen as self-serving or that I may have a vested interest in the position of the prime minister, but in upholding the principles of our Parliamentary System.

6)    I am dismayed and shocked that the Prime Minister (with the support of his Cabinet) is now seeking the consent of our YDP Agong to declare a state of emergency and presumably to put himself in charge of this emergency administration which would have far-reaching powers.

7)    I am not questioning the right of any Prime Minister to seek a declaration for a state of emergency with the YDP Agong as stipulated in our Constitution but rather the basis, rationale, timing and the real motive for it. We are now having a public healthcare crisis that is severely impacting the livelihood and economy of our people and which the Government may not be managing the crisis in the best interest of the public. The public and politicians across the divide, except for a few recalcitrants, are co-operating with the Government on the measures and SOPs. Our Parliamentary System of Democracy is working well and there are no mass rebellion or riots on our streets. I cannot see any honest basis for such a request while I can only suspect non-honourable motives behind it.

8)    If the Prime Minister were to get his way in imposing the proposed state of emergency, as an economist myself and the former Minister of Finance and former Minister of International Trade & Industry (and former Chairman of World Bank & IMF), I can say with some certainty that it may be the “final nail in the coffin” of our already battered economy. Local and foreign investors would shun us completely. Business confidence would be at ground zero.

APPENDIX: D

The view of a former Chief Secretary to the Government, TS Sheriff

I think the Malay Rulers will find it difficult to support the declaration of  emergency bcos unlike in 1969, today  they are heavily invested in the economy esp the stock market .
I also feel that my colleagues in Khazanah , EPF , Tabung Haji and PNB will be worried that the hundreds of billions of ringgit these GLICs  have in their stock market investments or in their listed companies  . 
How does this affect the ordinary Malays?   There  are about 15 million Malays who have invested their savings in the funds created by ASN , ASB . EPF contributors are abt 14 million. These funds invest a lot in KLSE. If the stock market collapses , they cant pay good dividends to the account holders.
In 1969 there was no PNB , so ordinary Malays did not bother abt the economy collapsing .
Its a different Malaysia today . Over the last 50 years , since early eighties ,the Malays are invested in the stock market directly or indirectly through ASN, ASB .
The emergency will push back the progress under the NEP for the middle class Malays . Many pensioners are now dependent on their ASN , ASB  dividend income to supplement their pension .
Entrepeneurs  will also feel the pain. They  use their stock holdings to apply for bank loans. If their shares lose in value, the banks will be reluctant to accept them as collateral for bank loans. Without access to bank borrowing , no business can plan their expansion .
So Mr PM , think hard before you declare an emergency . Tell frankly to the Rulers all the possible economic and social implications not only on their own wealth but also on the savings of their rakyat.


Sheriff

APPENDIX: E

Unconstitutional to declare emergency – Tommy Thomas

I HAVE, since March, scrupulously adhered to the convention that it is not proper for a former public officer to comment on the merits or demerits of policies and decisions made by his successor. But last night’s announcement that the prime minister requested the Yang di-Pertuan Agong to declare a national emergency imposes a responsibility on me not to remain silent. Hence, with a heavy heart, I pen my thoughts on the legality of the proposed move.

A proclamation of emergency under Article 150 of the federal constitution has tremendous negative consequences on the nation’s body politic and the exercise of freedoms and liberties by our citizens. Hence, the reluctance to rush into it. The opprobrium attached to emergencies led the government in October 2011 to revoke four proclamations that had marred our national psyche. The prime minister was then the deputy prime minister. Because the ramifications of an emergency are massive, the constitution has placed many safeguards against its use. The most obvious and most frequent abuse occurs when the prime minister of the day feels threatened as to the security of his tenure. Hence, checks and balances are built into Article 150, which has 13 sub-articles within it. It is a comprehensive code, and is the starting point of any discussion.

Article 150(1) provides that if the Agong is satisfied that a grave emergency exists, whereby the security, economic life or public order in Malaysia is threatened, he may issue a proclamation of emergency. Malaysia is a constitutional monarchy, and the Agong acts on the advice of the prime minister insofar as Article 150 is concerned. Hence, the true decision-maker is the prime minister, but the king has a residual discretion. In other words, it is not automatic that every time a prime minister desires a proclamation, the Agong must agree to it. The Agong is entitled to seek the advice of the Conference of Rulers, or indeed anyone whose advice the Agong values.

But for Article 150(1) to come into play, the conditions in the country or the circumstances are such that:

(i) A grave emergency exists;

(ii) whereby security;

(iii) economic life; or,

(iv) public order;

(v) is threatened.

None of these terms is defined in the constitution. Thus, they must be given their natural and ordinary meaning. Additionally, the draftsmen of the constitution placed an important safeguard: it is not any emergency, but one that is “grave”. This distinguishes it from a crisis or an “ordinary” emergency. It must be serious in nature, scale or magnitude.

It is difficult to find a single rational argument to support a case that there is a “grave emergency” today in Malaysia for whatever reason. Covid-19 has been with us since January. When it suits this government, it has boasted about how well they combated and contained the spread of Covid-19. And, they have objective grounds to make this claim, having regard to the performance of other countries. Hence, on a relative and comparative scale, Malaysia has handled Covid-19 well. But the same government cannot then claim that overnight, Covid-19 has became so “threatening” that we have a “grave emergency”. However, terrible Covid-19 is in Sabah, it does not warrant the declaration of a national emergency.

Although Covid-19 is the publicly stated reason, none of us is fooled. The true reason is that this prime minister is not confident that the Budget of his finance minister will be passed by the Dewan Rakyat when voted upon in early December. That would result in a lack of confidence in his government. They must resign then. Hence, the real reason is to ensure the survival of the prime minister in office. You reap what you sow. If you assumed power without being elected by the people of Malaysia, the same fate awaits you. You cannot stay in power by stopping others from aping you. That sums up the so-called case for an emergency. It is so self-serving that constitutionally, the prime minister is conflicted in seeking a proclamation of emergency solely to stay in office. His private interests are in conflict with his public duty.

Let me briefly consider the three preconditions in Article 150(1): security, economic life or public order. It is impossible for the prime minister to argue that the security of Malaysia is in any way affected by whether he continues to remain in office. Likewise, public order. That leaves “economic life”. This precondition has no application. Note that “health” is not a ground. This is hardly surprising. Nations have, over centuries, been affected by plague, tuberculosis, the Spanish flu and other contagious diseases. But they do not justify a national emergency. Ample public health and sanitisation measures can be put in place under the ordinary laws of the land, without resorting to emergency powers. In these circumstances, there are no legal grounds for the proclamation of an emergency in Malaysia today. It would, therefore, be unconstitutional.

Although an ouster clause is found in Article 150 (8), having regard to the development of constitutional law in seminal cases like Indira Gandhi and Semenyih Jaya, it can certainly been argued that the courts can review a decision to declare an emergency. Nearly half a century ago, the Teh Cheng Poh case considered the limits of the power of the executive to declare emergencies. A recent foreign example is illustrative of the worldwide trend in common law: the Brexit decision of the Supreme Court in the United Kingdom. In my opinion, a proclamation of emergency in present circumstances is justiciable before our courts.

A supreme irony is that the prime minister and his finance minister desire Parliament to be suspended, and for the Budget to be enforceable by executive action. This again would be unconstitutional because it would violate three sub-articles in Article 150 itself. Thus, Article 150(3) requires the proclamation to be laid before both Houses of Parliament. More significantly, the proclamation shall cease to have effect if a resolution is passed by both Houses “annulling such a proclamation”. Article 150(5) provides that while a proclamation is in force, “Parliament may make laws if it appears to Parliament the law is required”. Finally, Article 150(9) states that the Houses of Parliament should be regarded as sitting “only if the members of each House are respectively assembled together and carrying out the business of the House”.

It is plain and obvious that proclaiming an emergency does not have the intended result. Parliament continues to perform its duties. Hence, the Dewan Rakyat should sit in the normal way for the important Budget session in early November, as scheduled.

One would expect the finance minister, as an ex-banker, to advise his prime minister of the grave consequences to the economy if an emergency is declared. The ratings agencies will immediately downgrade our ratings, which means that borrowing costs will become more expensive, and perhaps, even more difficult. The share market will plunge, the ringgit will plummet, and business confidence will be shattered. All these predictable consequences would be self-inflicted solely to allow one man to remain as prime minister. Hence the “economic life” of Malaysia demands no emergency. Period.

For all these reasons, I implore the prime minister to withdraw this option. Rather, the problem is created by the 222 MPs. The solution, therefore, lies in their hands. If that means the prime minister and his political opponents have to spend next week horse-trading and bargaining for inclusion in a true unity government, they must undertake that with a spirit of consensus and compromise. The people of Malaysia, whom you are supposed to represent, are absolutely disgusted with the present state of affairs. The last thing we want is a national emergency caused solely by the ambitions and greed of politicians. – The Vibes, October 24, 2020

Tan Sri Tommy Thomas is a former attorney-general

EPILOGUE

Is it true for an imminent declaration of

No Emergency Brake for Malaysia?

One moonless night, a famous Sufist Joker called Moosruddin is looking for something under the street light.

A curious passerby asks him, “What are you looking?”

Moosruddin replies anxiously, “My house key.”

“Where do you think you have lost it ?”

“Inside the house.”

But why are you searching outside the house under the streetlight?”

“Here got light. My house is dark, no electricity. “

At that moment, Moosruddin’s house lit up, his locked door electronically opened.

The street lights went dark.

Standard